Great Depression - Wikipedia

Great Depression – Wikipedia

Worldwide financial despair (1929–1941)

The unemployment fee within the US throughout 1910–60, with the years of the Great Depression (1929–39) highlighted

The Great Depression was a extreme worldwide financial despair that happened principally through the Thirties, starting within the United States. The timing of the Great Depression various the world over; in most nations, it began in 1929 and lasted till the late Thirties.[1] It was the longest, deepest, and most widespread despair of the twentieth century.[2] The Great Depression is often used for example of how intensely the worldwide economic system can decline.[3]

The Great Depression began within the United States after a significant fall in inventory costs that started round September 4, 1929, and have become worldwide information with the inventory market crash of October 29, 1929, which was generally known as Black Tuesday. Between 1929 and 1932, worldwide gross home product (GDP) fell by an estimated 15%. By comparability, worldwide GDP fell by lower than 1% from 2008 to 2009 through the Great Recession.[4] Some economies began to get well by the mid-Thirties. However, in lots of nations, the detrimental results of the Great Depression lasted till the start of World War II.[5]

The Great Depression had devastating results in each wealthy and poor nations. Personal earnings, tax income, earnings and costs dropped, whereas worldwide commerce fell by greater than 50%. Unemployment within the U.S. rose to 23% and in some nations rose as excessive as 33%.[6]Cities around the globe have been hit exhausting, particularly these depending on heavy business. Construction was just about halted in lots of nations. Farming communities and rural areas suffered as crop costs fell by about 60%.[7][8][9] Facing plummeting demand with few different sources of jobs, areas depending on major sector industries equivalent to mining and logging suffered probably the most.[10]

Economic historians normally contemplate the catalyst of the Great Depression to be the sudden devastating collapse of U.S. inventory market costs, beginning on October 24, 1929. However, some dispute this conclusion and see the inventory crash as a symptom, fairly than a trigger, of the Great Depression.[6][11][12][full citation needed][clarification needed]

Even after the Wall Street Crash of 1929, the place the Dow Jones Industrial Average dropped from 381 to 198 over the course of two months, optimism endured for a while. The inventory market turned upward in early 1930, with the Dow returning to 294 (pre-depression ranges) in April 1930, earlier than steadily declining for years, to a low of 41 in 1932.[13]

At the start, governments and companies spent extra within the first half of 1930 than within the corresponding interval of the earlier yr. On the opposite hand, customers, a lot of whom suffered extreme losses within the inventory market the earlier yr, minimize their expenditures by 10%. In addition, starting within the mid-Thirties, a extreme drought ravaged the agricultural heartland of the U.S.[14]

Interest charges dropped to low ranges by mid-1930, however anticipated deflation and the persevering with reluctance of individuals to borrow meant that client spending and funding remained low.[15] By May 1930, vehicle gross sales declined to beneath the degrees of 1928. Prices, generally, started to say no, though wages held regular in 1930. Then a deflationary spiral began in 1931. Farmers confronted a worse outlook; declining crop costs and a Great Plains drought crippled their financial outlook. At its peak, the Great Depression noticed almost 10% of all Great Plains farms change arms regardless of federal help.[16]

The decline within the U.S. economic system was the issue that pulled down most different nations at first; then, inner weaknesses or strengths in every nation made circumstances worse or higher.[citation needed] Frantic makes an attempt by particular person nations to shore up their economies by protectionist insurance policies – such because the 1930 U.S. Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act and retaliatory tariffs in different nations – exacerbated the collapse in international commerce, contributing to the despair.[17] By 1933, the financial decline pushed world commerce to 1 third of its degree in comparison with 4 years earlier.[18]

Economic indicators

Change in financial indicators 1929–1932[19]
United States United Kingdom France Germany
Industrial manufacturing −46% −23% −24% −41%
Wholesale costs −32% −33% −34% −29%
Foreign commerce −70% −60% −54% −61%
Unemployment +607% +129% +214% +232%

Causes

U.S. industrial manufacturing, 1928–1939

The two basic competing financial theories of the Great Depression are the Keynesian (demand-driven) and the Monetarist rationalization.[20] There are additionally numerous heterodox theories that downplay or reject the reasons of the Keynesians and monetarists. The consensus amongst demand-driven theories is {that a} large-scale lack of confidence led to a sudden discount in consumption and funding spending. Once panic and deflation set in, many individuals believed they may keep away from additional losses by preserving away from the markets. Holding cash turned worthwhile as costs dropped decrease and a given amount of cash purchased ever extra items, exacerbating the drop in demand.[21] Monetarists imagine that the Great Depression began as an abnormal recession, however the shrinking of the cash provide vastly exacerbated the financial state of affairs, inflicting a recession to descend into the Great Depression.[22]

Economists and financial historians are virtually evenly break up as as to if the standard financial rationalization that financial forces have been the first explanation for the Great Depression is correct, or the standard Keynesian rationalization {that a} fall in autonomous spending, significantly funding, is the first rationalization for the onset of the Great Depression.[23] Today there may be additionally important tutorial help for the debt deflation idea and the expectations speculation that — constructing on the financial rationalization of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz — add non-monetary explanations.[24][25]

There is a consensus that the Federal Reserve System ought to have minimize quick the method of financial deflation and banking collapse, by increasing the cash provide and appearing as lender of final resort. If that they had carried out this, the financial downturn would have been far much less extreme and far shorter.[26]

Mainstream explanations

Modern mainstream economists see the explanations in

Insufficient spending, the cash provide discount, and debt on margin led to falling costs and additional bankruptcies (Irving Fisher’s debt deflation).

Keynesian view

British economist John Maynard Keynes argued in The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money that decrease mixture expenditures within the economic system contributed to an enormous decline in earnings and to employment that was properly beneath the typical. In such a state of affairs, the economic system reached equilibrium at low ranges of financial exercise and excessive unemployment.

Keynes’s fundamental concept was easy: to maintain folks absolutely employed, governments must run deficits when the economic system is slowing, because the personal sector wouldn’t make investments sufficient to maintain manufacturing on the regular degree and produce the economic system out of recession. Keynesian economists referred to as on governments throughout occasions of financial disaster to select up the slack by rising authorities spending or slicing taxes.

As the Depression wore on, Franklin D. Roosevelt tried public works, farm subsidies, and different gadgets to restart the U.S. economic system, however by no means fully gave up attempting to steadiness the funds. According to the Keynesians, this improved the economic system, however Roosevelt by no means spent sufficient to carry the economic system out of recession till the beginning of World War II.[28]

Monetarist view

Crowd at New York’s American Union Bank throughout a bank run early within the Great Depression

The monetarist rationalization was given by American economists Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz.[29] They argued that the Great Depression was attributable to the banking disaster that brought on one-third of all banks to fade, a discount of bank shareholder wealth and extra importantly financial contraction of 35%, which they referred to as “The Great Contraction”. This brought on a worth drop of 33% (deflation).[30] By not decreasing rates of interest, by not rising the financial base and by not injecting liquidity into the banking system to stop it from crumbling, the Federal Reserve passively watched the transformation of a standard recession into the Great Depression. Friedman and Schwartz argued that the downward flip within the economic system, beginning with the inventory market crash, would merely have been an abnormal recession if the Federal Reserve had taken aggressive motion.[31][32] This view was endorsed by Federal Reserve Governor Ben Bernanke in a speech honoring Friedman and Schwartz with this assertion:

Let me finish my speak by abusing barely my standing as an official consultant of the Federal Reserve. I wish to say to Milton and Anna: Regarding the Great Depression, you are proper. We did it. We’re very sorry. But because of you, we cannot do it once more.

The Federal Reserve allowed some giant public bank failures – significantly that of the New York Bank of United States – which produced panic and widespread runs on native banks, and the Federal Reserve sat idly by whereas banks collapsed. Friedman and Schwartz argued that, if the Fed had offered emergency lending to those key banks, or just purchased authorities bonds on the open market to offer liquidity and improve the amount of cash after the important thing banks fell, all the remainder of the banks wouldn’t have fallen after the big ones did, and the cash provide wouldn’t have fallen as far and as quick because it did.[35]

With considerably much less cash to go round, companies couldn’t get new loans and couldn’t even get their previous loans renewed, forcing many to cease investing. This interpretation blames the Federal Reserve for inaction, particularly the New York department.[36]

One motive why the Federal Reserve didn’t act to restrict the decline of the cash provide was the gold commonplace. At that point, the quantity of credit the Federal Reserve might difficulty was restricted by the Federal Reserve Act, which required 40% gold backing of Federal Reserve Notes issued. By the late Nineteen Twenties, the Federal Reserve had virtually hit the restrict of allowable credit that could possibly be backed by the gold in its possession. This credit was within the type of Federal Reserve demand notes.[37] A “promise of gold” is not so good as “gold in the hand”, significantly once they solely had sufficient gold to cowl 40% of the Federal Reserve Notes excellent. During the bank panics, a portion of these demand notes was redeemed for Federal Reserve gold. Since the Federal Reserve had hit its restrict on allowable credit, any discount in gold in its vaults needed to be accompanied by a better discount in credit. On April 5, 1933, President Roosevelt signed Executive Order 6102 making the personal possession of gold certificates, cash and bullion unlawful, decreasing the strain on Federal Reserve gold.[37]

Modern non-monetary explanations

The financial rationalization has two weaknesses. First, it isn’t capable of clarify why the demand for cash was falling extra quickly than the provision through the preliminary downturn in 1930–31.[23] Second, it isn’t capable of clarify why in March 1933 a restoration happened though quick time period rates of interest remained near zero and the cash provide was nonetheless falling. These questions are addressed by fashionable explanations that construct on the financial rationalization of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz however add non-monetary explanations.

Debt deflation
U.S. Public and Private Debt as a % of GDP.jpg

Irving Fisher argued that the predominant issue resulting in the Great Depression was a vicious circle of deflation and rising over-indebtedness.[38] He outlined 9 components interacting with each other beneath circumstances of debt and deflation to create the mechanics of growth to bust. The chain of occasions proceeded as follows:

  1. Debt liquidation and misery promoting
  2. Contraction of the cash provide as bank loans are paid off
  3. A fall within the degree of asset costs
  4. A nonetheless better fall within the internet value of companies, precipitating bankruptcies
  5. A fall in earnings
  6. A discount in output, in commerce and in employment
  7. Pessimism and lack of confidence
  8. Hoarding of cash
  9. A fall in nominal rates of interest and an increase in deflation adjusted rates of interest[38]

During the Crash of 1929 previous the Great Depression, margin necessities have been solely 10%.[39] Brokerage corporations, in different phrases, would lend $9 for each $1 an investor had deposited. When the market fell, brokers referred to as in these loans, which couldn’t be paid again.[40] Banks started to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors tried to withdraw their deposits en masse, triggering a number of bank runs. Government ensures and Federal Reserve banking rules to stop such panics have been ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to the lack of billions of {dollars} in belongings.[40]

Outstanding money owed turned heavier, as a result of costs and incomes fell by 20–50% however the money owed remained on the similar greenback quantity. After the panic of 1929 and through the first 10 months of 1930, 744 U.S. banks failed. (In all, 9,000 banks failed through the Thirties.) By April 1933, round $7 billion in deposits had been frozen in failed banks or these left unlicensed after the March Bank Holiday.[41] Bank failures snowballed as determined bankers referred to as in loans that debtors didn’t have time or cash to repay. With future earnings wanting poor, capital funding and development slowed or fully ceased. In the face of unhealthy loans and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks turned much more conservative of their lending.[40] Banks constructed up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A vicious cycle developed and the downward spiral accelerated.

The liquidation of debt couldn’t sustain with the autumn of costs that it brought on. The mass impact of the stampede to liquidate elevated the worth of every greenback owed, relative to the worth of declining asset holdings. The very effort of people to reduce their burden of debt successfully elevated it. Paradoxically, the extra the debtors paid, the extra they owed.[38] This self-aggravating course of turned a 1930 recession right into a 1933 nice despair.

Fisher’s debt-deflation idea initially lacked mainstream affect due to the counter-argument that debt-deflation represented not more than a redistribution from one group (debtors) to a different (collectors). Pure re-distributions shouldn’t have any important macroeconomic results.

Building on each the financial speculation of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz and the debt deflation speculation of Irving Fisher, Ben Bernanke developed another means during which the monetary disaster affected output. He builds on Fisher’s argument that dramatic declines within the worth degree and nominal incomes result in rising actual debt burdens, which in flip results in debtor insolvency and consequently lowers mixture demand; an additional worth degree decline would then end in a debt deflationary spiral. According to Bernanke, a small decline within the worth degree merely reallocates wealth from debtors to collectors with out doing injury to the economic system. But when the deflation is extreme, falling asset costs together with debtor bankruptcies result in a decline within the nominal worth of belongings on bank steadiness sheets. Banks will react by tightening their credit circumstances, which in flip results in a credit crunch that critically harms the economic system. A credit crunch lowers funding and consumption, which ends up in declining mixture demand and moreover contributes to the deflationary spiral.[42][43][44]

Expectations speculation

Since financial mainstream turned to the brand new neoclassical synthesis, expectations are a central aspect of macroeconomic fashions. According to Peter Temin, Barry Wigmore, Gauti B. Eggertsson and Christina Romer, the important thing to restoration and to ending the Great Depression was caused by a profitable administration of public expectations. The thesis is predicated on the commentary that after years of deflation and a really extreme recession vital financial indicators turned optimistic in March 1933 when Franklin D. Roosevelt took workplace. Consumer costs turned from deflation to a light inflation, industrial manufacturing bottomed out in March 1933, and funding doubled in 1933 with a turnaround in March 1933. There have been no financial forces to elucidate that turnaround. Money provide was nonetheless falling and short-term rates of interest remained near zero. Before March 1933, folks anticipated additional deflation and a recession in order that even rates of interest at zero didn’t stimulate funding. But when Roosevelt introduced main regime modifications, folks started to count on inflation and an financial growth. With these optimistic expectations, rates of interest at zero started to stimulate funding simply as they have been anticipated to do. Roosevelt’s fiscal and financial coverage regime change helped make his coverage goals credible. The expectation of upper future earnings and better future inflation stimulated demand and funding. The evaluation means that the elimination of the coverage dogmas of the gold commonplace, a balanced funds in occasions of disaster and small authorities led endogenously to a big shift in expectation that accounts for about 70–80% of the restoration of output and costs from 1933 to 1937. If the regime change had not occurred and the Hoover coverage had continued, the economic system would have continued its free fall in 1933, and output would have been 30% decrease in 1937 than in 1933.[45][46][47]

The recession of 1937–38, which slowed down financial restoration from the Great Depression, is defined by fears of the inhabitants that the reasonable tightening of the financial and financial coverage in 1937 have been first steps to a restoration of the pre-1933 coverage regime.[48]

Common place

There is frequent consensus amongst economists as we speak that the federal government and the central bank ought to work to maintain the interconnected macroeconomic aggregates of gross home product and cash provide on a steady progress path. When threatened by expectations of a despair, central banks ought to increase liquidity within the banking system and the federal government ought to minimize taxes and speed up spending in an effort to stop a collapse in cash provide and mixture demand.[49]

At the start of the Great Depression, most economists believed in Say’s legislation and the equilibrating powers of the market, and failed to know the severity of the Depression. Outright leave-it-alone liquidationism was a standard place, and was universally held by Austrian School economists.[50] The liquidationist place held {that a} despair labored to liquidate failed companies and investments that had been made out of date by technological improvement – releasing components of manufacturing (capital and labor) to be redeployed in different extra productive sectors of the dynamic economic system. They argued that even when self-adjustment of the economic system brought on mass bankruptcies, it was nonetheless one of the best course.[50]

Economists like Barry Eichengreen and J. Bradford DeLong be aware that President Herbert Hoover tried to maintain the federal funds balanced till 1932, when he misplaced confidence in his Secretary of the Treasury Andrew Mellon and changed him.[50][51][52] An more and more frequent view amongst financial historians is that the adherence of many Federal Reserve policymakers to the liquidationist place led to disastrous penalties.[51] Unlike what liquidationists anticipated, a big proportion of the capital inventory was not redeployed however vanished through the first years of the Great Depression. According to a examine by Olivier Blanchard and Lawrence Summers, the recession brought on a drop of internet capital accumulation to pre-1924 ranges by 1933.[53] Milton Friedman referred to as leave-it-alone liquidationism “dangerous nonsense”.[49] He wrote:

I believe the Austrian business-cycle idea has carried out the world quite a lot of hurt. If you return to the Thirties, which is a key level, right here you had the Austrians sitting in London, Hayek and Lionel Robbins, and saying you simply must let the underside drop out of the world. You’ve simply acquired to let it remedy itself. You cannot do something about it. You will solely make it worse. … I believe by encouraging that form of do-nothing coverage each in Britain and within the United States, they did hurt.[51]

Heterodox theories

Austrian School

Two outstanding theorists within the Austrian School on the Great Depression embody Austrian economist Friedrich Hayek and American economist Murray Rothbard, who wrote America’s Great Depression (1963). In their view, very similar to the monetarists, the Federal Reserve (created in 1913) shoulders a lot of the blame; nevertheless, in contrast to the Monetarists, they argue that the important thing explanation for the Depression was the growth of the cash provide within the Nineteen Twenties which led to an unsustainable credit-driven growth.[54]

In the Austrian view, it was this inflation of the cash provide that led to an unsustainable growth in each asset costs (shares and bonds) and capital items. Therefore, by the point the Federal Reserve tightened in 1928 it was far too late to stop an financial contraction.[54] In February 1929 Hayek revealed a paper predicting the Federal Reserve’s actions would result in a disaster beginning within the inventory and credit markets.[55]

According to Rothbard, the federal government help for failed enterprises and efforts to maintain wages above their market values truly extended the Depression.[56] Unlike Rothbard, after 1970 Hayek believed that the Federal Reserve had additional contributed to the issues of the Depression by allowing the cash provide to shrink through the earliest years of the Depression.[57] However, through the Depression (in 1932[58] and in 1934)[58] Hayek had criticized each the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England for not taking a extra contractionary stance.[58]

Hans Sennholz argued that almost all growth and busts that plagued the American economic system, equivalent to these in 1819–20, 1839–1843, 1857–1860, 1873–1878, 1893–1897, and 1920–21, have been generated by authorities making a growth by simple cash and credit, which was quickly adopted by the inevitable bust.[59]

Ludwig von Mises wrote within the Thirties: “Credit expansion cannot increase the supply of real goods. It merely brings about a rearrangement. It diverts capital investment away from the course prescribed by the state of economic wealth and market conditions. It causes production to pursue paths which it would not follow unless the economy were to acquire an increase in material goods. As a result, the upswing lacks a solid base. It is not real prosperity. It is illusory prosperity. It did not develop from an increase in economic wealth, i.e. the accumulation of savings made available for productive investment. Rather, it arose because the credit expansion created the illusion of such an increase. Sooner or later, it must become apparent that this economic situation is built on sand.”[60][61]

Inequality

Two economists of the Nineteen Twenties, Waddill Catchings and William Trufant Foster, popularized a idea that influenced many coverage makers, together with Herbert Hoover, Henry A. Wallace, Paul Douglas, and Marriner Eccles. It held the economic system produced greater than it consumed, as a result of the customers didn’t have sufficient earnings. Thus the unequal distribution of wealth all through the Nineteen Twenties brought on the Great Depression.[62][63]

According to this view, the basis explanation for the Great Depression was a world over-investment in heavy business capability in comparison with wages and earnings from impartial companies, equivalent to farms. The proposed answer was for the federal government to pump cash into the customers’ pockets. That is, it should redistribute buying energy, sustaining the economic base, and re-inflating costs and wages to pressure as a lot of the inflationary improve in buying energy into client spending. The economic system was overbuilt, and new factories weren’t wanted. Foster and Catchings beneficial[64] federal and state governments to begin giant development tasks, a program adopted by Hoover and Roosevelt.

Productivity shock

It can’t be emphasised too strongly that the [productivity, output, and employment] tendencies we’re describing are long-time tendencies and have been completely evident earlier than 1929. These tendencies are in nowise the results of the current despair, nor are they the results of the World War. On the opposite, the current despair is a collapse ensuing from these long-term tendencies.

The first three many years of the twentieth century noticed financial output surge with electrification, mass manufacturing, and motorized farm equipment, and due to the speedy progress in productiveness there was loads of extra manufacturing capability and the work week was being lowered. The dramatic rise in productiveness of main industries within the U.S. and the consequences of productiveness on output, wages and the workweek are mentioned by Spurgeon Bell in his e-book Productivity, Wages, and National Income (1940).[66]

The gold commonplace and the spreading of world despair

The gold commonplace was the first transmission mechanism of the Great Depression. Even nations that didn’t face bank failures and a financial contraction first hand have been pressured to affix the deflationary coverage since increased rates of interest in nations that carried out a deflationary coverage led to a gold outflow in nations with decrease rates of interest. Under the gold commonplace’s worth–specie move mechanism, nations that misplaced gold however nonetheless needed to keep up the gold commonplace needed to allow their cash provide to lower and the home worth degree to say no (deflation).[67][68]

There can be consensus that protectionist insurance policies, and primarily the passage of the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act, helped to exacerbate, and even trigger the Great Depression.[27]

Gold commonplace

The Depression in worldwide perspective[69]

Some financial research have indicated that simply because the downturn was unfold worldwide by the rigidities of the gold commonplace, it was suspending gold convertibility (or devaluing the forex in gold phrases) that did probably the most to make restoration potential.[70]

Every main forex left the gold commonplace through the Great Depression. The UK was the primary to take action. Facing speculative assaults on the pound and depleting gold reserves, in September 1931 the Bank of England ceased exchanging pound notes for gold and the pound was floated on international alternate markets.

Japan and the Scandinavian nations joined the UK in leaving the gold commonplace in 1931. Other nations, equivalent to Italy and the US, remained on the gold commonplace into 1932 or 1933, whereas a couple of nations within the so-called “gold bloc”, led by France and together with Poland, Belgium and Switzerland, stayed on the usual till 1935–36.

According to later evaluation, the earliness with which a rustic left the gold commonplace reliably predicted its financial restoration. For instance, The UK and Scandinavia, which left the gold commonplace in 1931, recovered a lot sooner than France and Belgium, which remained on gold for much longer. Countries equivalent to China, which had a silver commonplace, virtually averted the despair totally. The connection between leaving the gold commonplace as a robust predictor of that nation’s severity of its despair and the size of time of its restoration has been proven to be constant for dozens of nations, together with growing nations. This partly explains why the expertise and size of the despair differed between areas and states the world over.[71]

Breakdown of worldwide commerce

Many economists have argued that the sharp decline in worldwide commerce after 1930 helped to worsen the despair, particularly for nations considerably depending on international commerce. In a 1995 survey of American financial historians, two-thirds agreed that the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act (enacted June 17, 1930) at the very least worsened the Great Depression.[27] Most historians and economists blame this Act for worsening the despair by critically decreasing worldwide commerce and inflicting retaliatory tariffs in different nations. While international commerce was a small a part of general financial exercise within the U.S. and was concentrated in a couple of companies like farming, it was a a lot bigger consider many different nations.[72] The common advert valorem fee of duties on dutiable imports for 1921–1925 was 25.9% however beneath the brand new tariff it jumped to 50% throughout 1931–1935. In greenback phrases, American exports declined over the subsequent 4 years from about $5.2 billion in 1929 to $1.7 billion in 1933; so, not solely did the bodily quantity of exports fall, but in addition the costs fell by about 13 as written. Hardest hit have been farm commodities equivalent to wheat, cotton, tobacco, and lumber.

Governments around the globe took numerous steps into spending much less cash on international items equivalent to: “imposing tariffs, import quotas, and exchange controls”. These restrictions triggered a lot pressure amongst nations that had giant quantities of bilateral commerce, inflicting main export-import reductions through the despair. Not all governments enforced the identical measures of protectionism. Some nations raised tariffs drastically and enforced extreme restrictions on international alternate transactions, whereas different nations lowered “trade and exchange restrictions only marginally”:[73]

  • “Countries that remained on the gold standard, keeping currencies fixed, were more likely to restrict foreign trade.” These nations “resorted to protectionist policies to strengthen the balance of payments and limit gold losses.” They hoped that these restrictions and depletions would maintain the financial decline.[73]
  • Countries that deserted the gold commonplace, allowed their currencies to depreciate which brought on their steadiness of funds to strengthen. It additionally freed up financial coverage in order that central banks might decrease rates of interest and act as lenders of final resort. They possessed one of the best coverage devices to struggle the Depression and didn’t want protectionism.[73]
  • “The length and depth of a country’s economic downturn and the timing and vigor of its recovery are related to how long it remained on the gold standard. Countries abandoning the gold standard relatively early experienced relatively mild recessions and early recoveries. In contrast, countries remaining on the gold standard experienced prolonged slumps.”[73]
READ:   How to Defer Student Loans: 14 Steps (with Pictures)

Effect of tariffs

The consensus view amongst economists and financial historians (together with Keynesians, Monetarists and Austrian economists) is that the passage of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff exacerbated the Great Depression,[74] though there may be disagreement as to how a lot. In the favored view, the Smoot-Hawley Tariff was a number one explanation for the despair.[75][76] According to the U.S. Senate web site the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act is among the many most catastrophic acts in congressional historical past[77]

German banking disaster of 1931 and British disaster

The monetary disaster escalated uncontrolled in mid-1931, beginning with the collapse of the Credit Anstalt in Vienna in May.[78][79] This put heavy strain on Germany, which was already in political turmoil. With the rise in violence of Nazi and communist actions, in addition to investor nervousness at harsh authorities monetary insurance policies.[80] Investors withdrew their short-term cash from Germany, as confidence spiraled downward. The Reichsbank misplaced 150 million marks within the first week of June, 540 million within the second, and 150 million in two days, June 19–20. Collapse was at hand. U.S. President Herbert Hoover referred to as for a moratorium on Payment of conflict reparations. This angered Paris, which trusted a gradual move of German funds, but it surely slowed the disaster down, and the moratorium was agreed to in July 1931. An International convention in London later in July produced no agreements however on August 19 a standstill settlement froze Germany’s international liabilities for six months. Germany acquired emergency funding from personal banks in New York in addition to the Bank of International Settlements and the Bank of England. The funding solely slowed the method. Industrial failures started in Germany, a significant bank closed in July and a two-day vacation for all German banks was declared. Business failures have been extra frequent in July, and unfold to Romania and Hungary. The disaster continued to worsen in Germany, bringing political upheaval that lastly led to the approaching to energy of Hitler’s Nazi regime in January 1933.[81]

The world monetary disaster now started to overwhelm Britain; buyers the world over began withdrawing their gold from London on the fee of £2.5 million per day.[82] Credits of £25 million every from the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and a difficulty of £15 million fiduciary be aware slowed, however didn’t reverse the British disaster. The monetary disaster now brought on a significant political disaster in Britain in August 1931. With deficits mounting, the bankers demanded a balanced funds; the divided cupboard of Prime Minister Ramsay MacDonald’s Labour authorities agreed; it proposed to lift taxes, minimize spending, and most controversially, to chop unemployment advantages 20%. The assault on welfare was unacceptable to the Labour motion. MacDonald needed to resign, however King George V insisted he stay and kind an all-party coalition “National Government”. The Conservative and Liberals events signed on, together with a small cadre of Labour, however the overwhelming majority of Labour leaders denounced MacDonald as a traitor for main the brand new authorities. Britain went off the gold commonplace, and suffered comparatively lower than different main nations within the Great Depression. In the 1931 British election, the Labour Party was just about destroyed, leaving MacDonald as Prime Minister for a largely Conservative coalition.[83][84]

Turning level and restoration

The general course of the Depression within the United States, as mirrored in per-capita GDP (common earnings per particular person) proven in fixed yr 2000 {dollars}, plus a number of the key occasions of the interval. Dotted crimson line = long-term development 1920–1970.[85]

In most nations of the world, restoration from the Great Depression started in 1933.[11] In the U.S., restoration started in early 1933,[11] however the U.S. didn’t return to 1929 GNP for over a decade and nonetheless had an unemployment fee of about 15% in 1940, albeit down from the excessive of 25% in 1933.

There is not any consensus amongst economists relating to the driving force for the U.S. financial growth that continued by many of the Roosevelt years (and the 1937 recession that interrupted it). The frequent view amongst most economists is that Roosevelt’s New Deal insurance policies both brought on or accelerated the restoration, though his insurance policies have been by no means aggressive sufficient to carry the economic system fully out of recession. Some economists have additionally referred to as consideration to the optimistic results from expectations of reflation and rising nominal rates of interest that Roosevelt’s phrases and actions portended.[86][87] It was the rollback of those self same reflationary insurance policies that led to the interruption of a recession starting in late 1937.[88][89] One contributing coverage that reversed reflation was the Banking Act of 1935, which successfully raised reserve necessities, inflicting a financial contraction that helped to thwart the restoration.[90] GDP returned to its upward development in 1938.[85]

According to Christina Romer, the cash provide progress attributable to large worldwide gold inflows was an important supply of the restoration of the United States economic system, and that the economic system confirmed little signal of self-correction. The gold inflows have been partly because of devaluation of the U.S. greenback and partly because of deterioration of the political state of affairs in Europe.[91] In their e-book, A Monetary History of the United States, Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz additionally attributed the restoration to financial components, and contended that it was a lot slowed by poor administration of cash by the Federal Reserve System. Former (2006–2014) Chairman of the Federal Reserve Ben Bernanke agreed that financial components performed vital roles each within the worldwide financial decline and eventual restoration.[92] Bernanke additionally noticed a robust position for institutional components, significantly the rebuilding and restructuring of the monetary system,[93] and identified that the Depression must be examined in a global perspective.[94]

Role of ladies and family economics

Women’s major position was as housewives; with out a regular move of household earnings, their work turned a lot more durable in coping with meals and clothes and medical care. Birthrates fell in every single place, as kids have been postponed till households might financially help them. The common birthrate for 14 main nations fell 12% from 19.3 births per thousand inhabitants in 1930, to 17.0 in 1935.[95] In Canada, half of Roman Catholic girls defied Church teachings and used contraception to postpone births.[96]

Among the few girls within the labor pressure, layoffs have been much less frequent within the white-collar jobs they usually have been usually present in mild manufacturing work. However, there was a widespread demand to restrict households to 1 paid job, in order that wives may lose employment if their husband was employed.[97][98][99] Across Britain, there was an inclination for married girls to affix the labor pressure, competing for part-time jobs particularly.[100][101]

In France, very gradual inhabitants progress, particularly compared to Germany continued to be a severe difficulty within the Thirties. Support for rising welfare packages through the despair included a concentrate on girls within the household. The Conseil Supérieur de la Natalité campaigned for provisions enacted within the Code de la Famille (1939) that elevated state help to households with kids and required employers to guard the roles of fathers, even when they have been immigrants.[102]

In rural and small-town areas, girls expanded their operation of vegetable gardens to incorporate as a lot meals manufacturing as potential. In the United States, agricultural organizations sponsored packages to show housewives how you can optimize their gardens and to lift poultry for meat and eggs.[103] Rural girls made feed sack attire and different objects for themselves and their households and houses from feed sacks.[104] In American cities, African American girls quiltmakers enlarged their actions, promoted collaboration, and skilled neophytes. Quilts have been created for sensible use from numerous cheap supplies and elevated social interplay for ladies and promoted camaraderie and private achievement.[105]

Oral historical past offers proof for the way housewives in a contemporary industrial metropolis dealt with shortages of cash and assets. Often they up to date methods their moms used once they have been rising up in poor households. Cheap meals have been used, equivalent to soups, beans and noodles. They bought the most affordable cuts of meat—generally even horse meat—and recycled the Sunday roast into sandwiches and soups. They sewed and patched clothes, traded with their neighbors for outgrown objects, and made do with colder properties. New furnishings and home equipment have been postponed till higher days. Many girls additionally labored exterior the house, or took boarders, did laundry for commerce or money, and did stitching for neighbors in alternate for one thing they may provide. Extended households used mutual help—additional meals, spare rooms, repair-work, money loans—to assist cousins and in-laws.[106]

In Japan, official authorities coverage was deflationary and the alternative of Keynesian spending. Consequently, the federal government launched a marketing campaign throughout the nation to induce households to cut back their consumption, focusing consideration on spending by housewives.[107]

In Germany, the federal government tried to reshape personal family consumption beneath the Four-Year Plan of 1936 to realize German financial self-sufficiency. The Nazi girls’s organizations, different propaganda businesses and the authorities all tried to form such consumption as financial self-sufficiency was wanted to arrange for and to maintain the approaching conflict. The organizations, propaganda businesses and authorities employed slogans that referred to as up conventional values of thrift and wholesome residing. However, these efforts have been solely partly profitable in altering the conduct of housewives.[108]

World War II and restoration

A feminine manufacturing facility employee in 1942, Fort Worth, Texas. Women entered the workforce as males have been drafted into the armed forces.

The frequent view amongst financial historians is that the Great Depression ended with the arrival of World War II. Many economists imagine that authorities spending on the conflict brought on or at the very least accelerated restoration from the Great Depression, although some contemplate that it didn’t play a really giant position within the restoration, although it did assist in decreasing unemployment.[11][109][110][111]

The rearmament insurance policies main as much as World War II helped stimulate the economies of Europe in 1937–1939. By 1937, unemployment in Britain had fallen to 1.5 million. The mobilization of manpower following the outbreak of conflict in 1939 ended unemployment.[112]

When the United States entered the conflict in 1941, it lastly eradicated the final results from the Great Depression and introduced the U.S. unemployment fee down beneath 10%.[113] In the US, huge conflict spending doubled financial progress charges, both masking the consequences of the Depression or primarily ending the Depression. Businessmen ignored the mounting nationwide debt and heavy new taxes, redoubling their efforts for better output to reap the benefits of beneficiant authorities contracts.[114]

Socio-economic results

An impoverished American household residing in a shanty, 1936

The majority of nations arrange aid packages and most underwent some type of political upheaval, pushing them to the suitable. Many of the nations in Europe and Latin America that have been democracies noticed them overthrown by some type of dictatorship or authoritarian rule, most famously in Germany in 1933. The Dominion of Newfoundland gave up democracy voluntarily.

Australia

Australia’s dependence on agricultural and industrial exports meant it was one of many hardest-hit developed nations.[115] Falling export demand and commodity costs positioned huge downward pressures on wages. Unemployment reached a file excessive of 29% in 1932,[116] with incidents of civil unrest turning into frequent.[117] After 1932, a rise in wool and meat costs led to a gradual restoration.[118]

Canada

Harshly affected by each the worldwide financial downturn and the Dust Bowl, Canadian industrial manufacturing had by 1932 fallen to solely 58% of its 1929 determine, the second-lowest degree on the planet after the United States, and properly behind nations equivalent to Britain, which fell to solely 83% of the 1929 degree. Total nationwide earnings fell to 56% of the 1929 degree, once more worse than any nation aside from the United States. Unemployment reached 27% on the depth of the Depression in 1933.[119]

Chile

The League of Nations labeled Chile the nation hardest hit by the Great Depression as a result of 80% of presidency income got here from exports of copper and nitrates, which have been in low demand. Chile initially felt the impression of the Great Depression in 1930, when GDP dropped 14%, mining earnings declined 27%, and export earnings fell 28%. By 1932, GDP had shrunk to lower than half of what it had been in 1929, exacting a horrible toll in unemployment and enterprise failures.

Influenced profoundly by the Great Depression, many authorities leaders promoted the event of native business in an effort to insulate the economic system from future exterior shocks. After six years of presidency austerity measures, which succeeded in reestablishing Chile’s creditworthiness, Chileans elected to workplace through the 1938–58 interval a succession of middle and left-of-center governments interested by selling financial progress by authorities intervention.

Prompted partially by the devastating 1939 Chillán earthquake, the Popular Front authorities of Pedro Aguirre Cerda created the Production Development Corporation (Corporación de Fomento de la Producción, CORFO) to encourage with subsidies and direct investments an formidable program of import substitution industrialization. Consequently, as in different Latin American nations, protectionism turned an entrenched facet of the Chilean economic system.

China

China was largely unaffected by the Depression, primarily by having caught to the Silver commonplace. However, the U.S. silver buy act of 1934 created an insupportable demand on China’s silver cash, and so, ultimately, the silver commonplace was formally deserted in 1935 in favor of the 4 Chinese nationwide banks’[which?] “legal note” points. China and the British colony of Hong Kong, which adopted swimsuit on this regard in September 1935, can be the final to desert the silver commonplace. In addition, the Nationalist Government additionally acted energetically to modernize the authorized and penal techniques, stabilize costs, amortize money owed, reform the banking and forex techniques, construct railroads and highways, enhance public well being services, legislate towards site visitors in narcotics and increase industrial and agricultural manufacturing. On November 3, 1935, the federal government instituted the fiat forex (fapi) reform, instantly stabilizing costs and in addition elevating revenues for the federal government.

European African colonies

The sharp fall in commodity costs, and the steep decline in exports, damage the economies of the European colonies in Africa and Asia.[120][121] The agricultural sector was particularly exhausting hit. For instance, sisal had just lately develop into a significant export crop in Kenya and Tanganyika. During the despair, it suffered severely from low costs and advertising and marketing issues that affected all colonial commodities in Africa. Sisal producers established centralized controls for the export of their fibre.[122] There was widespread unemployment and hardship amongst peasants, labourers, colonial auxiliaries, and artisans.[123] The budgets of colonial governments have been minimize, which pressured the discount in ongoing infrastructure tasks, such because the constructing and upgrading of roads, ports and communications.[124] The funds cuts delayed the schedule for creating techniques of upper schooling.[125]

The despair severely damage the export-based Belgian Congo economic system due to the drop in worldwide demand for uncooked supplies and for agricultural merchandise. For instance, the value of peanuts fell from 125 to 25 centimes. In some areas, as within the Katanga mining area, employment declined by 70%. In the nation as an entire, the wage labour pressure decreased by 72.000 and lots of males returned to their villages. In Leopoldville, the inhabitants decreased by 33%, due to this labour migration.[126]

Political protests weren’t frequent. However, there was a rising demand that the paternalistic claims be honored by colonial governments to reply vigorously. The theme was that financial reforms have been extra urgently wanted than political reforms.[127] French West Africa launched an intensive program of instructional reform during which “rural schools” designed to modernize agriculture would stem the move of under-employed farm employees to cites the place unemployment was excessive. Students have been skilled in conventional arts, crafts, and farming methods and have been then anticipated to return to their very own villages and cities.[128]

France

The disaster affected France a bit later than different nations, hitting exhausting round 1931.[129] While the Nineteen Twenties grew on the very robust fee of 4.43% per yr, the Thirties fee fell to solely 0.63%.[130]

The despair was comparatively gentle: unemployment peaked beneath 5%, the autumn in manufacturing was at most 20% beneath the 1929 output; there was no banking disaster.[131]

However, the despair had drastic results on the native economic system, and partly explains the February 6, 1934 riots and much more the formation of the Popular Front, led by SFIO socialist chief Léon Blum, which gained the elections in 1936. Ultra-nationalist teams additionally noticed elevated reputation, though democracy prevailed into World War II.

France’s comparatively excessive diploma of self-sufficiency meant the injury was significantly lower than in neighbouring states like Germany.

Germany

The Great Depression hit Germany exhausting. The impression of the Wall Street Crash pressured American banks to finish the brand new loans that had been funding the repayments beneath the Dawes Plan and the Young Plan. The monetary disaster escalated uncontrolled in mid-1931, beginning with the collapse of the Credit Anstalt in Vienna in May.[79] This put heavy strain on Germany, which was already in political turmoil with the rise in violence of Nazi and communist actions, in addition to with investor nervousness at harsh authorities monetary insurance policies.[80] Investors withdrew their short-term cash from Germany, as confidence spiraled downward. The Reichsbank misplaced 150 million marks within the first week of June, 540 million within the second, and 150 million in two days, June 19–20. Collapse was at hand. U.S. President Herbert Hoover referred to as for a moratorium on Payment of conflict reparations. This angered Paris, which trusted a gradual move of German funds, but it surely slowed the disaster down, and the moratorium was agreed to in July 1931. An worldwide convention in London later in July produced no agreements however on August 19 a standstill settlement froze Germany’s international liabilities for six months. Germany acquired emergency funding from personal banks in New York in addition to the Bank of International Settlements and the Bank of England. The funding solely slowed the method. Industrial failures started in Germany, a significant bank closed in July and a two-day vacation for all German banks was declared. Business failures turned extra frequent in July, and unfold to Romania and Hungary.[81]

In 1932, 90% of German reparation funds have been cancelled (within the Nineteen Fifties, Germany repaid all its missed reparations money owed). Widespread unemployment reached 25% as each sector was damage. The authorities didn’t improve authorities spending to take care of Germany’s rising disaster, as they have been afraid {that a} high-spending coverage might result in a return of the hyperinflation that had affected Germany in 1923. Germany’s Weimar Republic was hit exhausting by the despair, as American loans to assist rebuild the German economic system now stopped.[132] The unemployment fee reached almost 30% in 1932, bolstering help for the Nazi (NSDAP) and Communist (KPD) events, inflicting the collapse of the politically centrist Social Democratic Party. Hitler ran for the Presidency in 1932, and whereas he misplaced to the incumbent Hindenburg within the election, it marked a degree throughout which each Nazi Party and the Communist events rose within the years following the crash to altogether possess a Reichstag majority following the overall election in July 1932.[133][134]

Hitler adopted an autarky financial coverage, making a community of shopper states and financial allies in central Europe and Latin America. By slicing wages and taking management of labor unions, plus public works spending, unemployment fell considerably by 1935. Large-scale army spending performed a significant position within the restoration.[135]

Greece

The reverberations of the Great Depression hit Greece in 1932. The Bank of Greece tried to undertake deflationary insurance policies to stave off the crises that have been happening in different nations, however these largely failed. For a short interval, the drachma was pegged to the U.S. greenback, however this was unsustainable given the nation’s giant commerce deficit and the one long-term results of this have been Greece’s international alternate reserves being virtually completely worn out in 1932. Remittances from overseas declined sharply and the worth of the drachma started to plummet from 77 drachmas to the greenback in March 1931 to 111 drachmas to the greenback in April 1931. This was particularly dangerous to Greece because the nation relied on imports from the UK, France, and the Middle East for a lot of requirements. Greece went off the gold commonplace in April 1932 and declared a moratorium on all curiosity funds. The nation additionally adopted protectionist insurance policies equivalent to import quotas, which a number of European nations did through the interval.

Protectionist insurance policies coupled with a weak drachma, stifling imports, allowed the Greek business to increase through the Great Depression. In 1939, the Greek industrial output was 179% that of 1928. These industries have been for probably the most half “built on sand” as one report of the Bank of Greece put it, as with out huge safety they’d not have been capable of survive. Despite the worldwide despair, Greece managed to endure comparatively little, averaging a mean progress fee of three.5% from 1932 to 1939. The dictatorial regime of Ioannis Metaxas took over the Greek authorities in 1936, and financial progress was robust within the years main as much as the Second World War.

Iceland

Icelandic post-World War I prosperity got here to an finish with the outbreak of the Great Depression. The Depression hit Iceland exhausting as the worth of exports plummeted. The whole worth of Icelandic exports fell from 74 million kronur in 1929 to 48 million in 1932, and was to not rise once more to the pre-1930 degree till after 1939.[136] Government interference within the economic system elevated: “Imports were regulated, trade with foreign currency was monopolized by state-owned banks, and loan capital was largely distributed by state-regulated funds”.[136] Due to the outbreak of the Spanish Civil War, which minimize Iceland’s exports of saltfish by half, the Depression lasted in Iceland till the outbreak of World War II (when costs for fish exports soared).[136]

India

How a lot India was affected has been hotly debated. Historians have argued that the Great Depression slowed long-term industrial improvement.[137] Apart from two sectors—jute and coal—the economic system was little affected. However, there have been main detrimental impacts on the jute business, as world demand fell and costs plunged.[138] Otherwise, circumstances have been pretty steady. Local markets in agriculture and small-scale business confirmed modest positive factors.[139]

Ireland

Frank Barry and Mary E. Daly have argued that:

Ireland was a largely agrarian economic system, buying and selling virtually completely with the UK, on the time of the Great Depression. Beef and dairy merchandise comprised the majority of exports, and Ireland fared properly relative to many different commodity producers, significantly within the early years of the despair.[140][141][142][143]

Italy

The Great Depression hit Italy very exhausting.[144] As industries got here near failure they have been purchased out by the banks in a largely illusionary bail-out—the belongings used to fund the purchases have been largely nugatory. This led to a monetary disaster peaking in 1932 and main authorities intervention. The Industrial Reconstruction Institute (IRI) was shaped in January 1933 and took management of the bank-owned firms, instantly giving Italy the most important state-owned industrial sector in Europe (excluding the united states). IRI did fairly properly with its new tasks—restructuring, modernising and rationalising as a lot because it might. It was a major consider post-1945 improvement. But it took the Italian economic system till 1935 to get well the manufacturing ranges of 1930—a place that was solely 60% higher than that of 1913.[145][146]

Japan

The Great Depression didn’t strongly have an effect on Japan. The Japanese economic system shrank by 8% throughout 1929–31. Japan’s Finance Minister Takahashi Korekiyo was the primary to implement what have come to be recognized as Keynesian financial insurance policies: first, by giant fiscal stimulus involving deficit spending; and second, by devaluing the forex. Takahashi used the Bank of Japan to sterilize the deficit spending and decrease ensuing inflationary pressures. Econometric research have recognized the fiscal stimulus as particularly efficient.[147]

The devaluation of the forex had a direct impact. Japanese textiles started to displace British textiles in export markets. The deficit spending proved to be most profound and went into the acquisition of munitions for the armed forces. By 1933, Japan was already out of the despair. By 1934, Takahashi realized that the economic system was in peril of overheating, and to keep away from inflation, moved to cut back the deficit spending that went in direction of armaments and munitions.

This resulted in a robust and swift detrimental response from nationalists, particularly these within the military, culminating in his assassination in the midst of the February 26 Incident. This had a chilling impact on all civilian bureaucrats within the Japanese authorities. From 1934, the army’s dominance of the federal government continued to develop. Instead of decreasing deficit spending, the federal government launched worth controls and rationing schemes that lowered, however didn’t get rid of inflation, which remained an issue till the top of World War II.

The deficit spending had a transformative impact on Japan. Japan’s industrial manufacturing doubled through the Thirties. Further, in 1929 the checklist of the most important corporations in Japan was dominated by mild industries, particularly textile firms (a lot of Japan’s automakers, equivalent to Toyota, have their roots within the textile business). By 1940 mild business had been displaced by heavy business as the most important corporations contained in the Japanese economic system.[148]

Latin America

Because of excessive ranges of U.S. funding in Latin American economies, they have been severely broken by the Depression. Within the area, Chile, Bolivia and Peru have been significantly badly affected.[149]

Before the 1929 disaster, hyperlinks between the world economic system and Latin American economies had been established by American and British funding in Latin American exports to the world. As a end result, Latin Americans export industries felt the despair rapidly. World costs for commodities equivalent to wheat, espresso and copper plunged. Exports from all of Latin America to the U.S. fell in worth from $1.2 billion in 1929 to $335 million in 1933, rising to $660 million in 1940.

But however, the despair led the realm governments to develop new native industries and increase consumption and manufacturing. Following the instance of the New Deal, governments within the space accepted rules and created or improved welfare establishments that helped thousands and thousands of latest industrial employees to realize a greater way of life.

Netherlands

From roughly 1931 to 1937, the Netherlands suffered a deep and exceptionally lengthy despair. This despair was partly attributable to the after-effects of the Stock Market Crash of 1929 within the US, and partly by inner components within the Netherlands. Government coverage, particularly the very late dropping of the Gold Standard, performed a job in prolonging the despair. The Great Depression within the Netherlands led to some political instability and riots, and might be linked to the rise of the Dutch fascist political occasion NSB. The despair within the Netherlands eased off considerably on the finish of 1936, when the federal government lastly dropped the Gold Standard, however actual financial stability didn’t return till after World War II.[150]

New Zealand

New Zealand was particularly susceptible to worldwide despair, because it relied virtually totally on agricultural exports to the United Kingdom for its economic system. The drop in exports led to a scarcity of disposable earnings from the farmers, who have been the mainstay of the native economic system. Jobs disappeared and wages plummeted, leaving folks determined and charities unable to manage. Work aid schemes have been the one authorities help obtainable to the unemployed, the speed of which by the early Thirties was formally round 15%, however unofficially almost twice that degree (official figures excluded Māori and girls). In 1932, riots occurred among the many unemployed in three of the nation’s major cities (Auckland, Dunedin, and Wellington). Many have been arrested or injured by the robust official dealing with of those riots by police and volunteer “special constables”.[151]

READ:   A Student Loan Borrower’s Complete Guide to Public Service Loan Forgiveness

Poland

Poland was affected by the Great Depression longer and stronger than different nations because of insufficient financial response of the federal government and the pre-existing financial circumstances of the nation. At that point, Poland was beneath the authoritarian rule of Sanacja, whose chief, Józef Piłsudski, was against leaving the gold commonplace till his dying in 1935. As a end result, Poland was unable to carry out a extra lively financial and funds coverage. Additionally, Poland was a comparatively younger nation that emerged merely 10 years earlier after being partitioned between German, Russian and the Austro-Hungarian Empires for over a century. Prior to independence, the Russian half exported 91% of its exports to Russia correct, whereas the German half exported 68% to Germany correct. After independence, these markets have been largely misplaced, as Russia remodeled into USSR that was principally a closed economic system, and Germany was in a tariff conflict with Poland all through the Nineteen Twenties.[152]

Industrial manufacturing fell considerably: in 1932 exhausting coal manufacturing was down 27% in comparison with 1928, metal manufacturing was down 61%, and iron ore manufacturing famous a 89% lower.[153] On the opposite hand, electrotechnical, leather-based, and paper industries famous marginal will increase in manufacturing output. Overall, industrial manufacturing decreased by 41%.[154] A definite characteristic of the Great Depression in Poland was the de-concentration of business, as bigger conglomerates have been much less versatile and paid their employees greater than smaller ones.

Unemployment fee rose considerably (as much as 43%) whereas nominal wages fell by 51% in 1933 and 56% in 1934, relative to 1928. However, actual wages fell much less because of the authorities’s coverage of lowering price of residing, significantly meals expenditures (meals costs have been down by 65% in 1935 in comparison with 1928 worth ranges). Material circumstances deprivation led to strikes, a few of them violent or violently pacified – like in Sanok (March 6, 1930), Lesko county (June 21 – July 9, 1932) and Zawiercie (April 18, 1930).

To undertake to the disaster, Polish authorities employed deflation strategies equivalent to excessive rates of interest, credit limits and funds austerity to maintain a hard and fast alternate fee with currencies tied to the gold commonplace. Only in late 1932 the federal government created a plan to struggle the financial disaster.[155] Part of the plan was mass public works scheme, using as much as 100,000 folks in 1935.[153] After Piłsudski’s dying, in 1936 the gold commonplace regime was relaxed, and launching the event of the Central Industrial Region kicked off the economic system, to over 10% annual progress fee within the 1936-1938 interval.

Portugal

Already beneath the rule of a dictatorial junta, the Ditadura Nacional, Portugal suffered no turbulent political results of the Depression, though António de Oliveira Salazar, already appointed Minister of Finance in 1928 vastly expanded his powers and in 1932 rose to Prime Minister of Portugal to discovered the Estado Novo, an authoritarian corporatist dictatorship. With the funds balanced in 1929, the consequences of the despair have been relaxed by harsh measures in direction of funds steadiness and autarky, inflicting social discontent however stability and, finally, a powerful financial progress.[156]

Puerto Rico

In the years instantly previous the despair, detrimental developments within the island and world economies perpetuated an unsustainable cycle of subsistence for a lot of Puerto Rican employees. The Nineteen Twenties introduced a dramatic drop in Puerto Rico’s two major exports, uncooked sugar and occasional, because of a devastating hurricane in 1928 and the plummeting demand from international markets within the latter half of the last decade. 1930 unemployment on the island was roughly 36% and by 1933 Puerto Rico’s per capita earnings dropped 30% (by comparability, unemployment within the United States in 1930 was roughly 8% reaching a top of 25% in 1933).[157][158] To present aid and financial reform, the United States authorities and Puerto Rican politicians equivalent to Carlos Chardon and Luis Muñoz Marín created and administered first the Puerto Rico Emergency Relief Administration (PRERA) 1933 after which in 1935, the Puerto Rico Reconstruction Administration (PRRA).[159]

Romania

Romania was additionally affected by the Great Depression.[160][161]

South Africa

As world commerce slumped, demand for South African agricultural and mineral exports fell drastically. The Carnegie Commission on Poor Whites had concluded in 1931 that just about one-third of Afrikaners lived as paupers. The social discomfort attributable to the despair was a contributing issue within the 1933 break up between the “gesuiwerde” (purified) and “smelter” (fusionist) factions inside the National Party and the National Party’s subsequent fusion with the South African Party.[162][163] Unemployment packages have been begun that targeted totally on the white inhabitants.[164]

Soviet Union

The Soviet Union was the world’s solely socialist state with little or no worldwide commerce. Its economic system was not tied to the remainder of the world and was principally unaffected by the Great Depression.[165] Its pressured transformation from a rural to an industrial society succeeded in build up heavy business, at the price of thousands and thousands of lives in rural Russia and Ukraine.[166]

At the time of the Depression, the Soviet economic system was rising steadily, fuelled by intensive funding in heavy business. The obvious financial success of the Soviet Union at a time when the capitalist world was in disaster led many Western intellectuals to view the Soviet system favorably. Jennifer Burns wrote:

As the Great Depression floor on and unemployment soared, intellectuals started unfavorably evaluating their faltering capitalist economic system to Russian Communism […] More than ten years after the Revolution, Communism was lastly reaching full flower, based on New York Times reporter Walter Duranty, a Stalin fan who vigorously debunked accounts of the Ukraine famine, a man-made catastrophe that would depart thousands and thousands useless.[167]

Due to having little or no worldwide commerce and its coverage of isolation, they didn’t obtain the advantages of worldwide commerce as soon as the despair ran its course, and have been nonetheless successfully poorer than most developed nations at their worst sufferings within the disaster.

The Great Depression brought on mass immigration to the Soviet Union, principally from Finland and Germany. Soviet Russia was at first pleased to assist these immigrants settle, as a result of they believed they have been victims of capitalism who had come to assist the Soviet trigger. However, when the Soviet Union entered the conflict in 1941, most of those Germans and Finns have been arrested and despatched to Siberia, whereas their Russian-born kids have been positioned in orphanages. Their destiny stays unknown.[168]

Spain

Spain had a comparatively remoted economic system, with excessive protecting tariffs and was not one of many major nations affected by the Depression. The banking system held up properly, as did agriculture.[169]

By far probably the most severe detrimental impression got here after 1936 from the heavy destruction of infrastructure and manpower by the civil conflict, 1936–39. Many proficient employees have been pressured into everlasting exile. By staying impartial within the Second World War, and promoting to each side[clarification needed], the economic system averted additional disasters.[170]

Sweden

By the Thirties, Sweden had what America’s Life journal referred to as in 1938 the “world’s highest standard of living”. Sweden was additionally the primary nation worldwide to get well fully from the Great Depression. Taking place amid a short-lived authorities and a less-than-a-decade previous Swedish democracy, occasions equivalent to these surrounding Ivar Kreuger (who finally dedicated suicide) stay notorious in Swedish historical past. The Social Democrats beneath Per Albin Hansson shaped their first long-lived authorities in 1932 based mostly on robust interventionist and welfare state insurance policies, monopolizing the workplace of Prime Minister till 1976 with the only real and short-lived exception of Axel Pehrsson-Bramstorp’s “summer cabinet” in 1936. During forty years of hegemony, it was probably the most profitable political occasion within the historical past of Western liberal democracy.[171]

Thailand

In Thailand, then generally known as the Kingdom of Siam, the Great Depression contributed to the top of absolutely the monarchy of King Rama VII within the Siamese revolution of 1932.[citation needed]

United Kingdom

Unemployed folks in entrance of a workhouse in London, 1930

The World Depression broke at a time when the United Kingdom had nonetheless not absolutely recovered from the consequences of the First World War greater than a decade earlier. The nation was pushed off the gold commonplace in 1931.

The world monetary disaster started to overwhelm Britain in 1931; buyers the world over began withdrawing their gold from London on the fee of £2.5 million per day.[82] Credits of £25 million every from the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and a difficulty of £15 million fiduciary be aware slowed, however didn’t reverse the British disaster. The monetary disaster now brought on a significant political disaster in Britain in August 1931. With deficits mounting, the bankers demanded a balanced funds; the divided cupboard of Prime Minister Ramsay MacDonald’s Labour authorities agreed; it proposed to lift taxes, minimize spending and most controversially, to chop unemployment advantages by 20%. The assault on welfare was completely unacceptable to the Labour motion. MacDonald needed to resign, however King George V insisted he stay and kind an all-party coalition “National Government”. The Conservative and Liberals events signed on, together with a small cadre of Labour, however the overwhelming majority of Labour leaders denounced MacDonald as a traitor for main the brand new authorities. Britain went off the gold commonplace, and suffered comparatively lower than different main nations within the Great Depression. In the 1931 British election, the Labour Party was just about destroyed, leaving MacDonald as Prime Minister for a largely Conservative coalition.[172][84]

The results on the northern industrial areas of Britain have been speedy and devastating, as demand for conventional industrial merchandise collapsed. By the top of 1930 unemployment had greater than doubled from 1 million to 2.5 million (20% of the insured workforce), and exports had fallen in worth by 50%. In 1933, 30% of Glaswegians have been unemployed because of the extreme decline in heavy business. In some cities and cities within the north east, unemployment reached as excessive as 70% as shipbuilding fell by 90%.[173] The National Hunger March of September–October 1932 was the most important[174] of a collection of starvation marches in Britain within the Nineteen Twenties and Thirties. About 200,000 unemployed males have been despatched to the work camps, which continued in operation till 1939.[175]

In the much less industrial Midlands and Southern England, the consequences have been short-lived and the later Thirties have been a affluent time. Growth in fashionable manufacture {of electrical} items and a growth within the motor automotive business was helped by a rising southern inhabitants and an increasing center class. Agriculture additionally noticed a growth throughout this era.[176]

United States

Unemployed males standing in line exterior a despair soup kitchen in Chicago 1931.

Hoover’s first measures to fight the despair have been based mostly on voluntarism by companies to not scale back their workforce or minimize wages however companies had little selection: wages have been lowered, employees have been laid off, and investments postponed.[177][178]

In June 1930, Congress accepted the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act which raised tariffs on 1000’s of imported objects. The intent of the Act was to encourage the acquisition of American-made merchandise by rising the price of imported items, whereas elevating income for the federal authorities and defending farmers. Most nations that traded with the US elevated tariffs on American-made items in retaliation, decreasing worldwide commerce, and worsening the Depression.[179]

In 1931, Hoover urged bankers to arrange the National Credit Corporation[180] in order that huge banks might assist failing banks survive. But bankers have been reluctant to put money into failing banks, and the National Credit Corporation did virtually nothing to deal with the issue.[181]

Shacks on the Anacostia flats, Washington, D.C. put up by the Bonus Army (World War I veterans) burning after the battle with the 1,000 troopers accompanied by tanks and machine weapons, 1932[182]

By 1932, unemployment had reached 23.6%, peaking in early 1933 at 25%.[183] Drought endured within the agricultural heartland, companies and households defaulted on file numbers of loans, and greater than 5,000 banks had failed.[184] Hundreds of 1000’s of Americans discovered themselves homeless, and started congregating in shanty cities – dubbed “Hoovervilles” – that started to appear throughout the nation.[185] In response, President Hoover and Congress accepted the Federal Home Loan Bank Act, to spur new dwelling development, and scale back foreclosures. The last try of the Hoover Administration to stimulate the economic system was the passage of the Emergency Relief and Construction Act (ERA) which included funds for public works packages equivalent to dams and the creation of the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC) in 1932. The Reconstruction Finance Corporation was a Federal company with the authority to lend as much as $2 billion to rescue banks and restore confidence in monetary establishments. But $2 billion was not sufficient to avoid wasting all of the banks, and bank runs and bank failures continued.[177] Quarter by quarter the economic system went downhill, as costs, earnings and employment fell, resulting in the political realignment in 1932 that delivered to energy Franklin Delano Roosevelt. It is vital to notice, nevertheless, that after volunteerism failed, Hoover developed concepts that laid the framework for components of the New Deal.[citation needed]

Buried equipment in a barn lot; South Dakota, May 1936. The Dust Bowl on the Great Plains coincided with the Great Depression.[186]

Shortly after President Franklin Delano Roosevelt was inaugurated in 1933, drought and erosion mixed to trigger the Dust Bowl, shifting a whole lot of 1000’s of displaced individuals off their farms within the Midwest. From his inauguration onward, Roosevelt argued that restructuring of the economic system can be wanted to stop one other despair or keep away from prolonging the present one. New Deal packages sought to stimulate demand and supply work and aid for the impoverished by elevated authorities spending and the establishment of economic reforms.

During a “bank holiday” that lasted 5 days, the Emergency Banking Act was signed into legislation. It offered for a system of reopening sound banks beneath Treasury supervision, with federal loans obtainable if wanted. The Securities Act of 1933 comprehensively regulated the securities business. This was adopted by the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 which created the Securities and Exchange Commission. Although amended, key provisions of each Acts are nonetheless in pressure. Federal insurance of bank deposits was offered by the FDIC, and the Glass–Steagall Act.

The Agricultural Adjustment Act offered incentives to chop farm manufacturing in an effort to elevate farming costs. The National Recovery Administration (NRA) made quite a lot of sweeping modifications to the American economic system. It pressured companies to work with authorities to set worth codes by the NRA to struggle deflationary “cut-throat competition” by the setting of minimal costs and wages, labor requirements, and aggressive circumstances in all industries. It inspired unions that will elevate wages, to extend the buying energy of the working class. The NRA was deemed unconstitutional by the Supreme Court of the United States in 1935.

CCC employees setting up highway, 1933. Over 3 million unemployed younger males have been taken out of the cities and positioned into 2,600+ work camps managed by the CCC.[187]

These reforms, along with a number of different aid and restoration measures, are referred to as the First New Deal. Economic stimulus was tried by a brand new alphabet soup of businesses arrange in 1933 and 1934 and beforehand extant businesses such because the Reconstruction Finance Corporation. By 1935, the “Second New Deal” added Social Security (which was later significantly prolonged by the Fair Deal), a jobs program for the unemployed (the Works Progress Administration, WPA) and, by the National Labor Relations Board, a robust stimulus to the expansion of labor unions. In 1929, federal expenditures constituted solely 3% of the GDP. The nationwide debt as a proportion of GNP rose beneath Hoover from 20% to 40%. Roosevelt saved it at 40% till the conflict started, when it soared to 128%.

By 1936, the principle financial indicators had regained the degrees of the late Nineteen Twenties, aside from unemployment, which remained excessive at 11%, though this was significantly decrease than the 25% unemployment fee seen in 1933. In the spring of 1937, American industrial manufacturing exceeded that of 1929 and remained degree till June 1937. In June 1937, the Roosevelt administration minimize spending and elevated taxation in an try to steadiness the federal funds.[188]
The American economic system then took a pointy downturn, lasting for 13 months by most of 1938. Industrial manufacturing fell virtually 30 per cent inside a couple of months and manufacturing of sturdy items fell even sooner. Unemployment jumped from 14.3% in 1937 to 19.0% in 1938, rising from 5 million to greater than 12 million in early 1938.[189] Manufacturing output fell by 37% from the 1937 peak and was again to 1934 ranges.[190]

The WPA employed 2–3 million at unskilled labor.

Producers lowered their expenditures on sturdy items, and inventories declined, however private earnings was solely 15% decrease than it had been on the peak in 1937. As unemployment rose, customers’ expenditures declined, resulting in additional cutbacks in manufacturing. By May 1938 retail gross sales started to extend, employment improved, and industrial manufacturing turned up after June 1938.[191] After the restoration from the Recession of 1937–38, conservatives have been capable of kind a bipartisan conservative coalition to cease additional growth of the New Deal and, when unemployment dropped to 2% within the early Nineteen Forties, they abolished WPA, CCC and the PWA aid packages. Social Security remained in place.

Between 1933 and 1939, federal expenditure tripled, and Roosevelt’s critics charged that he was turning America right into a socialist state.[192] The Great Depression was a major issue within the implementation of social democracy and deliberate economies in European nations after World War II (see Marshall Plan). Keynesianism typically remained probably the most influential financial college within the United States and in components of Europe till the durations between the Seventies and the Eighties, when Milton Friedman and different neoliberal economists formulated and propagated the newly created theories of neoliberalism and included them into the Chicago School of Economics instead strategy to the examine of economics. Neoliberalism went on to problem the dominance of the Keynesian college of Economics within the mainstream academia and policy-making within the United States, having reached its peak in reputation within the election of the presidency of Ronald Reagan within the United States, and Margaret Thatcher within the United Kingdom.[193]

Literature

And the good homeowners, who should lose their land in an upheaval, the good homeowners with entry to historical past, with eyes to learn historical past and to know the good reality: when property accumulates in too few arms it’s taken away. And that companion reality: when a majority of the persons are hungry and chilly they are going to take by pressure what they want. And the little screaming indisputable fact that sounds by all historical past: repression works solely to strengthen and knit the repressed.

–John Steinbeck, The Grapes of Wrath[194]

The Great Depression has been the topic of a lot writing, as authors have sought to judge an period that brought on each monetary and emotional trauma. Perhaps probably the most noteworthy and well-known novel written on the topic is The Grapes of Wrath, revealed in 1939 and written by John Steinbeck, who was awarded each the Nobel Prize for literature and the Pulitzer Prize for the work. The novel focuses on a poor household of sharecroppers who’re pressured from their dwelling as drought, financial hardship, and modifications within the agricultural business happen through the Great Depression. Steinbeck’s Of Mice and Men is one other vital novella a couple of journey through the Great Depression. Additionally, Harper Lee’s To Kill a Mockingbird is about through the Great Depression. Margaret Atwood’s Booker prize-winning The Blind Assassin is likewise set within the Great Depression, centering on a privileged socialite’s love affair with a Marxist revolutionary. The period spurred the resurgence of social realism, practiced by many who began their writing careers on aid packages, particularly the Federal Writers’ Project within the U.S.[195][196][197][198]

A variety of works for youthful audiences are additionally set through the Great Depression, amongst them the Kit Kittredge collection of American Girl books written by Valerie Tripp and illustrated by Walter Rane, launched to tie in with the dolls and playsets offered by the corporate. The tales, which occur through the early to mid Thirties in Cincinnati, focuses on the modifications introduced by the Depression to the titular character’s household and the way the Kittredges handled it.[199] A theatrical adaptation of the collection entitled Kit Kittredge: An American Girl was later launched in 2008 to optimistic critiques.[200][201] Similarly, Christmas After All, a part of the Dear America collection of books for older ladies, happen in Thirties Indianapolis; whereas Kit Kittredge is advised in a third-person viewpoint, Christmas After All is within the type of a fictional journal as advised by the protagonist Minnie Swift as she recounts her experiences through the period, particularly when her household takes in an orphan cousin from Texas.[202]

Naming

The time period “The Great Depression” is most ceaselessly attributed to British economist Lionel Robbins, whose 1934 e-book The Great Depression is credited with formalizing the phrase,[203] although Hoover is extensively credited with popularizing the time period,[203][204] informally referring to the downturn as a despair, with such makes use of as “Economic depression cannot be cured by legislative action or executive pronouncement” (December 1930, Message to Congress), and “I need not recount to you that the world is passing through a great depression” (1931).

The time period “depression” to seek advice from an financial downturn dates to the nineteenth century, when it was utilized by various Americans and British politicians and economists. Indeed, the primary main American financial disaster, the Panic of 1819, was described by then-president James Monroe as “a depression”,[203] and the newest financial disaster, the Depression of 1920–21, had been known as a “depression” by then-president Calvin Coolidge.

Financial crises have been historically known as “panics”, most just lately the foremost Panic of 1907, and the minor Panic of 1910–11, although the 1929 disaster was referred to as “The Crash”, and the time period “panic” has since fallen out of use. At the time of the Great Depression, the time period “The Great Depression” was already used to seek advice from the interval 1873–96 (within the United Kingdom), or extra narrowly 1873–79 (within the United States), which has retroactively been renamed the Long Depression.[205]

Other “great depressions”

Other financial downturns have been referred to as a “great depression”, however none had been as widespread, or lasted for thus lengthy. Various states have skilled transient or prolonged durations of financial downturns, which have been known as “depressions”, however none have had such a widespread international impression.[citation needed]

The collapse of the Soviet Union, and the breakdown of financial ties which adopted, led to a extreme financial disaster and catastrophic fall within the requirements of residing within the Nineteen Nineties in post-Soviet states and the previous Eastern Bloc,[206] which was even worse than the Great Depression.[207][208] Even earlier than Russia’s monetary disaster of 1998, Russia’s GDP was half of what it had been within the early Nineteen Nineties,[208] and a few populations are nonetheless poorer as of 2009 than they have been in 1989, together with Moldova, Central Asia, and the Caucasus.[citation needed]

Comparison with the Great Recession

The worldwide financial decline after 2008 has been in comparison with the Thirties.[209][210][211][212][213]

The causes of the Great Recession appear much like the Great Depression, however important variations exist. The earlier chairman of the Federal Reserve, Ben Bernanke, had extensively studied the Great Depression as a part of his doctoral work at MIT, and carried out insurance policies to govern the cash provide and rates of interest in ways in which weren’t carried out within the Thirties. Bernanke’s insurance policies will undoubtedly be analyzed and scrutinized within the years to come back, as economists debate the knowledge of his selections. Generally talking, the restoration of the world’s monetary techniques tended to be faster through the Great Depression of the Thirties versus the late-2000s recession.

If we distinction the Thirties with the Crash of 2008 the place gold went by the roof, it’s clear that the U.S. greenback on the gold commonplace was a very totally different animal compared to the fiat free-floating U.S. greenback forex we’ve got as we speak. Both currencies in 1929 and 2008 have been the U.S. greenback, however analogously it’s as if one was a Saber-toothed tiger and the opposite is a Bengal tiger; they’re two fully totally different animals. Where we’ve got skilled inflation because the Crash of 2008, the state of affairs was a lot totally different within the Thirties when deflation set in. Unlike the deflation of the early Thirties, the U.S. economic system at the moment seems to be in a “liquidity trap,” or a state of affairs the place financial coverage is unable to stimulate an economic system again to well being.

In phrases of the inventory market, almost three years after the 1929 crash, the DJIA dropped 8.4% on August 12, 1932. Where we’ve got skilled nice volatility with giant intraday swings up to now two months, in 2011, we’ve got not skilled any record-shattering each day share drops to the tune of the Thirties. Where many people might have that ’30s feeling, in mild of the DJIA, the CPI, and the nationwide unemployment fee, we’re merely not residing within the ’30s. Some people might really feel as if we live in a despair, however for a lot of others the present international monetary disaster merely doesn’t really feel like a despair akin to the Thirties.[214]

1928 and 1929 have been the occasions within the twentieth century that the wealth hole reached such skewed extremes;[215] half the unemployed had been out of labor for over six months, one thing that was not repeated till the late-2000s recession. 2007 and 2008 finally noticed the world attain new ranges of wealth hole inequality that rivalled the years of 1928 and 1929.

See additionally

General

References

  1. ^ John A. Garraty, The Great Depression (1986)
  2. ^ Charles Duhigg, “Depression, You Say? Check Those Safety Nets”, The New York Times, March 23, 2008.
  3. ^ Barry Eichengreen, Hall of Mirrors: The Great Depression, The Great Recession, and the Uses-and Misuses-of History (2014)
  4. ^ Roger Lowenstein, “History Repeating,” Wall Street Journal Jan 14, 2015
  5. ^ Garraty, Great Depression (1986) ch1
  6. ^ a b Frank, Robert H.; Bernanke, Ben S. (2007). Principles of Macroeconomics (third ed.). Boston: McGraw-Hill/Irwin. p. 98. ISBN 978-0-07-319397-7.
  7. ^ “Commodity Data”. US Bureau of Labor Statistics. Retrieved November 30, 2008.
  8. ^ Cochrane, Willard W. (1958). “Farm Prices, Myth and Reality”: 15.
  9. ^ “World Economic Survey 1932–33”. League of Nations: 43.
  10. ^ Mitchell, Depression Decade
  11. ^ a b c d “Great Depression”, Encyclopædia Britannica
  12. ^ “Economics focus: The Great Depression”. The Economist.
  13. ^ “1998/99 Prognosis Based Upon 1929 Market Autopsy”. Gold Eagle. Archived from the unique on May 17, 2008. Retrieved May 22, 2008.
  14. ^ “Drought: A Paleo Perspective – 20th Century Drought”. National Climatic Data Center. Retrieved April 5, 2009.
  15. ^ Hamilton, James (1987). “Monetary Factors in the Great Depression”. Journal of Monetary Economics. 19 (2): 145–69. doi:10.1016/0304-3932(87)90045-6.
  16. ^ “The Great Depression”. drought.unl.edu. Retrieved March 29, 2018.
  17. ^ Richard, Clay Hanes (editor) (July 2002). Historic Events for Students: The Great Depression (Volume I ed.). Gale. ISBN 978-0-7876-5701-7.CS1 maint: additional textual content: authors checklist (hyperlink)
  18. ^ Tignor, Tignor, Robert L. (October 28, 2013). Worlds collectively, worlds aside: a historical past of the world from the beginnings of humankind to the current (Fourth ed.). New York. ISBN 978-0-393-92207-3. OCLC 854609153.
  19. ^ Jerome Blum, Rondo Cameron, Thomas G. Barnes, The European world: a historical past (2nd ed 1970) 885 pp.
  20. ^ author, Full Bio Follow Linkedin Follow Twitter Nick Lioudis is a; Professional, Multimedia; guide; Lioudis, content material supervisor for Bread He has additionally spent 10+ years as a journalist Learn about our editorial insurance policies Nick. “What is the difference between Keynesian and monetarist economics?”. Investopedia. Retrieved July 12, 2021.
  21. ^ “Great Depression – Causes of the decline”. Encyclopedia Britannica. Retrieved July 12, 2021.
  22. ^ Hayes, Adam. “What is a Monetarist?”. Investopedia. Retrieved July 12, 2021.
  23. ^ a b Whaples, Robert (1995). “Where is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions” (PDF). The Journal of Economic History. 55 (1). p. 150. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.482.4975. doi:10.1017/S0022050700040602. JSTOR 2123771.
  24. ^ Mendoza, Enrique G.; Smith, Katherine A. (September 1, 2006). “Quantitative implications of a debt-deflation theory of Sudden Stops and asset prices”. Journal of International Economics. 70 (1): 82–114. doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.06.016. ISSN 0022-1996.
  25. ^ Buraschi, Andrea; Jiltsov, Alexei (February 1, 2005). “Inflation risk premia and the expectations hypothesis”. Journal of Financial Economics. 75 (2): 429–490. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.07.003. ISSN 0304-405X.
  26. ^ Whaples, Robert (1995). “Where is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions” (PDF). The Journal of Economic History. 55 (1). p. 143. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.482.4975. doi:10.1017/S0022050700040602. JSTOR 2123771.
  27. ^ a b c Whaples, Robert (1995). “Where is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions”. The Journal of Economic History. 55 (1): 139–154. doi:10.1017/S0022050700040602. JSTOR 2123771.
  28. ^ Klein, Lawrence R. (1947). “The Keynesian Revolution”. New York: Macmillan: 56–58, 169, 177–179. ; Rosenof, Theodore (1997). Economics within the Long Run: New Deal Theorists and Their Legacies, 1933–1993. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. ISBN 0-8078-2315-5.
  29. ^ A Monetary History of the United States, 1857–1960. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1963.
  30. ^ Randall E. Parker (2003), Reflections on the Great Depression, Edward Elgar Publishing, ISBN 978-1-84376-550-9, pp. 11–12
  31. ^ Friedman, Milton; Anna Jacobson Schwartz (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New ed.). Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0691137940.
  32. ^ Bernanke, Ben (2000). Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton University Press. p. 7. ISBN 0-691-01698-4.
  33. ^ Ben S. Bernanke (8 November 2002), “FederalReserve.gov: Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke” Conference to Honor Milton Friedman, University of Chicago
  34. ^ Friedman, Milton; Schwartz, Anna (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New ed.). Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0691137940.
  35. ^ Krugman, Paul (February 15, 2007). “Who Was Milton Friedman?”. The New York Review of Books. Archived from the unique on April 10, 2008. Retrieved May 22, 2008.
  36. ^ G. Edward Griffin (1998). The Creature from Jekyll Island: A Second Look on the Federal Reserve (3d ed.). p. 503. ISBN 978-0-912986-39-5.
  37. ^ a b Frank Freidel (1973), Franklin D. Roosevelt: Launching the New Deal, ch. 19, Little, Brown & Co.
  38. ^ a b c Fisher, Irving (October 1933). “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions”. Econometrica. The Econometric Society. 1 (4): 337–57. doi:10.2307/1907327. JSTOR 1907327. S2CID 35564016.
  39. ^ Fortune, Peter (September–October 2000). “Margin Requirements, Margin Loans, and Margin Rates: Practice and Principles – analysis of history of margin credit regulations – Statistical Data Included”. New England Economic Review. Archived from the unique on May 27, 2012.
  40. ^ a b c “Bank Failures”. Living History Farm. Archived from the unique on February 19, 2009. Retrieved May 22, 2008.
  41. ^ “Friedman and Schwartz, Monetary History of the United States”, 352
  42. ^ Randall E. Parker, Reflections on the Great Depression, Edward Elgar Publishing, 2003, ISBN 978-1-84376-550-9, pp. 14–15
  43. ^ Bernanke, Ben S (June 1983). “Non-Monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression” (PDF). The American Economic Review. The American Economic Association. 73 (3): 257–276. JSTOR 1808111. Archived from the unique (PDF) on November 18, 2017. Retrieved February 22, 2021.
  44. ^ Mishkin, Fredric (December 1978). “The Household Balance and the Great Depression”. Journal of Economic History. 38 (4): 918–937. doi:10.1017/S0022050700087167.
  45. ^ Gauti B. Eggertsson, Great Expectations and the End of the Depression, American Economic Review 2008, 98:4, 1476–1516
  46. ^ Christina Romer, “The Fiscal Stimulus, Flawed but Valuable”, The New York Times, October 20, 2012.
  47. ^ Peter Temin, Lessons from the Great Depression, MIT Press, 1992, ISBN 978-0-262-26119-7, pp. 87–101.
  48. ^ Eggertsson, Gauti B. (2008). “Great Expectations and the End of the Depression”. The American Economic Review. 98 (4). p. 1480. doi:10.1257/aer.98.4.1476. hdl:10419/60661. JSTOR 29730131.
  49. ^ a b De Long, J. Bradford (December 1990). “Liquidation’ Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression”. NBER Working Paper No. 3546: 1. doi:10.3386/w3546.
  50. ^ a b c Randall E. Parker, Reflections on the Great Depression, Elgar Publishing, 2003, ISBN 978-1-84376-335-2, p. 9
  51. ^ a b c White, Lawrence (2008). “Did Hayek and Robbins Deepen the Great Depression?”. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 40 (4): 751–768. doi:10.1111/j.1538-4616.2008.00134.x.
  52. ^ De Long, J. Bradford (December 1990). “Liquidation’ Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression”. NBER Working Paper No. 3546: 5. doi:10.3386/w3546.
  53. ^ De Long, J. Bradford (December 1990). “Liquidation’ Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression”. NBER Working Paper No. 3546: 33. doi:10.3386/w3546.
  54. ^ a b Murray Rothbard, America’s Great Depression (Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2000), pp. 159–163.
  55. ^ Steele, G. R. (2001). Keynes and Hayek. Routledge. p. 9. ISBN 978-0-415-25138-9.
  56. ^ Rothbard, America’s Great Depression, pp. 19–21.
  57. ^
    For Hayek’s view, see:

    • Diego Pizano, Conversations with Great Economists: Friedrich A. Hayek, John Hicks, Nicholas Kaldor, Leonid V. Kantorovich, Joan Robinson, Paul A.Samuelson, Jan Tinbergen (Jorge Pinto Books, 2009).

    For Rothbard’s view, see:

    • Murray Rothbard, A History of Money and Banking within the United States (Ludwig von Mises Institute), pp. 293–294.

  58. ^ a b c John Cunningham Wood, Robert D. Wood, Friedrich A. Hayek, Taylor & Francis, 2004, ISBN 978-0-415-31057-4, p. 115
  59. ^ Sennholz, Hans (October 1, 1969). “The Great Depression”. Foundation for Economic Education. Retrieved October 23, 2016.
  60. ^ Mises, Ludwig (August 18, 2014). “The Causes of the Economic Crisis, and Other Essays Before and After the Great Depression”. Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved October 24, 2016.
  61. ^ Bonner, Bill (February 25, 2011). “Buying Bad Debt to Return Bank Solvency”. Business Insider. Retrieved October 24, 2016.
  62. ^ Dorfman 1959
  63. ^ Allgoewer, Elisabeth (May 2002). “Underconsumption theories and Keynesian economics. Interpretations of the Great Depression” (PDF). Discussion Paper No. 2002–14.
  64. ^ The Road to Plenty (1928)
  65. ^ Hubbert, M. King (1940). “Man Hours and Distribution, Derived from Man Hours: A Declining Quantity, Technocracy, Series A, No. 8, August 1936″.
  66. ^ Bell, Spurgeon (1940). “Productivity, Wages and National Income, The Institute of Economics of the Brookings Institution”.
  67. ^ Peter Temin, Gianni Toniolo, The World Economy between the Wars, Oxford University Press, 2008, ISBN 978-0-19-804201-3, p. 106
  68. ^ Randall E. Parker, Reflections on the Great Depression, Elgar publishing, 2003, ISBN 978-1-84376-335-2, p. 22.
  69. ^ International information from Maddison, Angus. “Historical Statistics for the World Economy: 1–2003 AD”.[permanent dead link]. Gold dates culled from historic sources, principally Eichengreen, Barry (1992). Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-506431-3.
  70. ^ Eichengreen, Barry (1992). Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-506431-3.
  71. ^ Bernanke, Ben (March 2, 2004). “Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke: Money, Gold and the Great Depression”. At the H. Parker Willis Lecture in Economic Policy, Washington and Lee University, Lexington, Virginia.
  72. ^ “The World in Depression”. Mount Holyoke College. Archived from the unique on March 10, 2008. Retrieved May 22, 2008.
  73. ^ a b c d Eichengreen, B.; Irwin, D. A. (2010). “The Slide to Protectionism in the Great Depression: Who Succumbed and Why?” (PDF). Journal of Economic History. 70 (4): 871–897. doi:10.1017/s0022050710000756. S2CID 18906612.
  74. ^ Whaples, Robert (March 1995). “Where Is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions”. The Journal of Economic History. Cambridge University Press. 55 (1): 144. doi:10.1017/S0022050700040602. JSTOR 2123771.
  75. ^ “Protectionism and the Great Depression”, Paul Krugman, New York Times, November 30, 2009
  76. ^ Barry Eichengreen, Douglas Irwin (March 17, 2009). “The protectionist temptation: Lessons from the Great Depression for today”. VOX.
  77. ^ “The Senate Passes the Smoot-Hawley Tariff”. United States Senate. United States Senate. Retrieved May 3, 2020.
  78. ^ Charles Loch Mowat, Britain between the wars, 1918–1940 (1955) pp. 379–385.
  79. ^ a b William Ashworth, A brief historical past of the worldwide economic system since 1850 (2nd ed. 1962) pp. 237–244.
  80. ^ a b Isabel Schnabel, “The German twin crisis of 1931”. Journal of Economic History 64#3 (2004): 822–871.
  81. ^ a b H. V. Hodson (1938), Slump and Recovery, 1929–1937 (London), pp. 64–76.
  82. ^ a b Williams, David (1963). “London and the 1931 financial crisis”. Economic History Review. 15 (3): 513–528. doi:10.2307/2592922. JSTOR 2592922.
  83. ^ Mowat (1955), Britain between the wars, 1918–1940, pp. 386–412.
  84. ^ a b Sean Glynn and John Oxborrow (1976), Interwar Britain : a social and financial historical past, pp. 67–73.
  85. ^ a b Per-capita GDP information from MeasuringWorth: What Was the U.S. GDP Then?
  86. ^ Gauti B. Eggertsson, “Great Expectations and the End of the Depression”, American Economic Review 98, No. 4 (September 2008): 1476–1516
  87. ^ “Was the New Deal Contractionary?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 264, October 2006, Gauti B. Eggertsson
  88. ^ “The Mistake of 1937: A General Equilibrium Analysis”, Monetary and Economic Studies 24, No. S-1 (December 2006), Boj.or.jp Archived August 11, 2015, on the Wayback Machine
  89. ^ Eggertsson, Gauti B. “A Reply to Steven Horwitz’s Commentary on ‘Great Expectations and the End of the Great Depression“. Econ Journal Watch. 7 (3): 197–204.
  90. ^ Steven Horwitz, “Unfortunately Unfamiliar with Robert Higgs and Others: A Rejoinder to Gauti Eggertsson on the 1930s”, Econ Journal Watch 8(1), 2, January 2011. [1]
  91. ^ Romer, Christina D. (December 1992). “What Ended the Great Depression” (PDF). Journal of Economic History. 52 (4): 757–84. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.207.844. doi:10.1017/S002205070001189X. Archived from the unique (PDF) on January 17, 2013. financial improvement have been essential to the restoration implies that self-correction performed little position within the progress of actual output
  92. ^ Ben Bernanke. Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-01698-6. p. 7
  93. ^ Ben S. Bernanke, “Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propaga-tion of the Great Depression”, The American Economic Review 73, No. 3 (June 1983): 257–276, obtainable from the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank assortment at Stlouisfed.org
  94. ^ Bernanke, Ben S. (February 1995). “The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach” (PDF). Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. Fraser.stlouisfed.org. 27 (1): 1–28. doi:10.2307/2077848. JSTOR 2077848. Retrieved October 16, 2014.
  95. ^ W. S. Woytinsky and E. S. Woytinsky, World inhabitants and manufacturing: tendencies and outlook (1953) p. 148
  96. ^ Denyse Baillargeon, Making Do: Women, Family and Home in Montreal through the Great Depression (Wilfrid Laurier University Press, 1999), p. 159.
  97. ^ Stephenson, Jill (2014). Women in Nazi Germany. Taylor & Francis. pp. 3–5. ISBN 978-1-317-87607-6.
  98. ^ Susan Okay. Foley (2004). Women in France Since 1789: The Meanings of Difference. Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 186–90. ISBN 978-0-230-80214-8.
  99. ^ Srigley, Katrina (2010). Breadwinning Daughters: Young Working Women in a Depression-era City, 1929–1939. University of Toronto Press. p. 135. ISBN 978-1-4426-1003-3.
  100. ^ Jessica S. Bean, ‘To help keep the home going’: female labour supply in interwar London”. Economic History Review (2015) 68#2 pp. 441–470.
  101. ^ Deirdre Beddoe, Back to Home and Duty: Women Between the Wars, 1918–1939 (1989).
  102. ^ Camiscioli, Elisa (2001). “Producing Citizens, Reproducing the ‘French Race’: Immigration, Demography, and Pronatalism in Early Twentieth‐Century France”. Gender & History. 13 (3): 593–621. doi:10.1111/1468-0424.00245. PMID 18198513.
  103. ^ Ann E. McCleary, ‘I Was Really Proud of Them’: Canned Raspberries and Home Production During the Farm Depression”. Augusta Historical Bulletin (2010), Issue 46, pp. 14–44.
  104. ^ Vogelsang, Willem. “3. Feedsacks and the Great Depression”. trc-leiden.nl. Retrieved March 21, 2020.
  105. ^ Klassen, Tari (2008). “How Depression-Era Quiltmakers Constructed Domestic Space: An Interracial Processual Study”. Midwestern Folklore: Journal of the Hoosier Folklore Society. 34 (2): 17–47.
  106. ^ Baillargeon, Making Do: Women, Family and Home in Montreal through the Great Depression (1999), pp. 70, 108, 136–138, 159.
  107. ^ Metzler, Mark (2004). “Woman’s Place in Japan’s Great Depression: Reflections on the Moral Economy of Deflation”. Journal of Japanese Studies. 30 (2): 315–352. doi:10.1353/jjs.2004.0045. S2CID 146273711.
  108. ^ Reagin, N. R. (2001). “Marktordnung and Autarkic Housekeeping: Housewives and Private Consumption under the Four-Year Plan, 1936–1939”. German History. 19 (2): 162–184. doi:10.1191/026635501678771619. PMID 19610237.
  109. ^ Referring to the impact of World War II spending on the economic system, economist John Kenneth Galbraith stated, “One could not have had a better demonstration of the Keynesian ideas.” Daniel Yergin, William Cran (writers / producer) (2002). Commanding Heights, see chapter 6 video or transcript (TV documentary). U.S.: PBS.
  110. ^ Romer, Christina D. (1992). “What Ended the Great Depression?”. Journal of Economic History. 52 (4): 757–784. doi:10.1017/S002205070001189X. fiscal coverage was of little consequence whilst late as 1942, suggests an attention-grabbing twist on the same old view that World War II brought on, or at the very least accelerated, the restoration from the Great Depression.
  111. ^ Higgs, Robert (March 1, 1992). “Wartime Prosperity? A Reassessment of the U.S. Economy in the 1940s”. The Journal of Economic History. 52 (1): 41–60. doi:10.1017/S0022050700010251. ISSN 1471-6372. S2CID 154484756.
  112. ^ “Great Depression and World War II”. Library of Congress.
  113. ^ “Depression & WWII” Archived June 25, 2009, on the Wayback Machine. Americaslibrary.gov.
  114. ^ Richard J. Jensen, “The causes and cures of unemployment in the Great Depression”. Journal of Interdisciplinary History 19.4 (1989): 553–583.
  115. ^ Geoffrey Lawrence, Capitalism and the Countryside: The rural disaster in Australia (Pluto Press, 1987)
  116. ^ A Century of Change within the Australian Labour Market, Australian Bureau of Statistics
  117. ^ John Birmingham (2000). Leviathan: The unauthorised biography of Sydney. Random House. ISBN 978-0-09-184203-1
  118. ^ Judy Mackinolty, ed. The Wasted Years?: Australia’s Great Depression (Allen & Unwin, 1981).
  119. ^ 1929–1939 – The Great Depression Archived January 27, 2009, on the Wayback Machine, Source: Bank of Canada
  120. ^ Anthony Latham and John Heaton, The Depression and the Developing World, 1914–1939 (1981).
  121. ^ Coquery-Vidrovitch, C. (1977). “Mutation de l’Impérialisme Colonial Français dans les Années 30”. African Economic History (in French) (4): 103–152. doi:10.2307/3601244. JSTOR 3601244.
  122. ^ Westcott, Nicholas (1984). “The East African sisal industry, 1929–1949: the marketing of a colonial commodity during depression and war”. Journal of African History. 25 (4): 445–461. doi:10.1017/s0021853700028486.
  123. ^ R. Olufeni Ekundare, An Economic History of Nigeria 1860–1960 (1973) on-line pp. 104–226.
  124. ^ Olubomehin, O.O. (2002). “Road Transportation and the Economy of South-Western Nigeria, 1920-1939”. Lagos Historical Review. 2: 106–121.
  125. ^ Lungu, Gatian F. (1993). “Educational Policy-Making in Colonial Zambia: The Case of Higher Education for Africans from 1924 to 1964”. The Journal of Negro History. 78 (4): 207–232. doi:10.2307/2717416. JSTOR 2717416. S2CID 149538992.
  126. ^ R. Anstey, King Leopold’s Legacy: The Congo beneath Belgian Rule 1908–1960 (1966), p. 109.
  127. ^ Ochonu, Moses (2009). “Critical convergence: the Great Depression and the meshing of Nigerian and British anti-colonial polemic”. Canadian Journal of African Studies. 43 (2): 245–281. doi:10.1080/00083968.2010.9707572. S2CID 142695035.
  128. ^ Gamble, Harry (2009). “Les paysans de l’empire: écoles rurales et imaginaire colonial en Afrique occidentale française dans les années 1930”. Cahiers d’Études Africaines. 49 (3): 775–803. doi:10.4000/etudesafricaines.15630.
  129. ^ Laufenburger, Henry (1936). “France and the Depression”. International Affairs. 15 (2): 202–224. JSTOR 2601740.
  130. ^ Jean-Pierre Dormois, The French Economy within the Twentieth Century (2004) p. 31
  131. ^ Beaudry, Paul; Portier, Franck (2002). “The French Depression in the 1930s”. Review of Economic Dynamics. 5: 73–99. doi:10.1006/redy.2001.0143.
  132. ^ About the Great Depression, University of Illinois
  133. ^ Germany – Economic, Public Broadcasting Service (PBS).
  134. ^ “The History Place – Rise of Hitler: Hitler Runs for President”. www.historyplace.com. Retrieved October 23, 2016.
  135. ^ Adam Tooze, The Wages of Destruction: The Making and Breaking of the Nazi Economy (2007)
  136. ^ a b c Karlsson, Gunnar (2000). History of Iceland. pp. 308–12.
  137. ^ Manikumar, Okay. A. (2003). A Colonial Economy within the Great Depression, Madras (1929–1937).
  138. ^ Samita Sen, “Labour, Organization and Gender: The Jute Industry in India in the 1930s,” in Helmut Konrad and Wolfgang Maderthaner, eds. Routes Into the Abyss: Coping with Crises within the Thirties (2013) pp. 152–66.
  139. ^ Simmons, Colin (1987). “The Great Depression and Indian Industry: Changing Interpretations and Changing Perceptions”. Modern Asian Studies. 21 (3): 585–623. doi:10.1017/S0026749X00009215. JSTOR 312643.
  140. ^ Frank Barry and Mary F. Daly, “Concurrent Irish Perspectives on the Great Depression” (2010) [ online ]
  141. ^ Frank Barry and Mary E. Daly, “Irish Perceptions of the Great Depression” in Michael Psalidopoulos, The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012) pp. 395–424.
  142. ^ See additionally B. Girvin, Between Two Worlds: Politics and Economy in Independent Ireland (Dublin: Gill and Macmillan, 1989).
  143. ^ Barry, Frank, and Mary E. Daly. “Irish Perceptions of the Great Depression” (No. iiisdp349. IIIS, 2011.) Online
  144. ^ Vera Zamagni, The financial historical past of Italy 1860–1990 (Oxford University Press, 1993)
  145. ^ Fabrizio Mattesini, and Beniamino Quintieri. “Italy and the Great Depression: An analysis of the Italian economy, 1929–1936.” Explorations in Economic History (1997) 34#3 pp: 265–294.
  146. ^ Fabrizio Mattesini and Beniamino Quintieri. “Does a reduction in the length of the working week reduce unemployment? Some evidence from the Italian economy during the Great Depression.” Explorations in Economic History (2006), 43#3, pp. 413–37.
  147. ^ Myung Soo Cha, “Did Takahashi Korekiyo Rescue Japan from the Great Depression?”, The Journal of Economic History 63, No. 1 (March 2003): 127–144.
  148. ^ (For extra on the Japanese economic system within the Thirties see “MITI and the Japanese Miracle” by Chalmers Johnson.)
  149. ^ Rosemary Thorp, Latin America within the Thirties: the position of the periphery in world disaster (Palgrave Macmillan, 2000).
  150. ^ E.H. Kossmann, The Low Countries: 1780–1940 (1978).
  151. ^ “Social Welfare and The State: Great Depression”, Museum of New Zealand Te Papa Tongarewa.
  152. ^ “II RP była gospodarczą porażką. Mity na jej temat są bardzo szkodliwe [TOP 2018]”. forsal.pl (in Polish). November 3, 2018. Retrieved July 29, 2021.
  153. ^ a b “Wielki kryzys gospodarczy w Polsce”. histmag.org. Retrieved July 29, 2021.
  154. ^ “Wielki kryzys w Polsce. Zbankrutowało niemal 25% firm, a produkt krajowy spadł o ponad połowę”. WielkaHistoria (in Polish). November 9, 2020. Retrieved July 29, 2021.
  155. ^ “140 lat temu urodził się Bolesław Wieniawa-Długoszowski”. dzieje.pl (in Polish). Retrieved July 29, 2021.
  156. ^ José Cardozo, “The great depression and Portugal” in Michael Psalidopoulos, ed. (2012). The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context Athens: Alpha Bank, ISBN 978-960-99793-6-8. pp. 361–94 Online
  157. ^ Rodriguez, Manuel (2011). A New Deal for the Tropics. Princeton: Markus Wiener. p. 23.
  158. ^ “Graph of U.S. Unemployment Rate: 1930–1945”. American Social History Project. Retrieved April 19, 2017.
  159. ^ Dietz, James (1986). Economic History of Puerto Rico. Princeton: Princeton University Press. pp. 154–55. ISBN 0-691-02248-8.
  160. ^ Blejan, Elisabeta; Costache, Brîndușa; Aloman, Adriana (2009). “The National Bank of Romania during the Great Depression – 1929-1933” (PDF). Fourth Conference of Southeast Europe Monetary History Network (SEEMHN). National Bank of Serbia (8): 1–34.
  161. ^ Chiappini, Raphaël; Torre, Dominique; Tosi, Elise (2009). “Romania’s unsustainable stabilization: 1929-1933” (PDF). GREDEG Working Papers. Groupe de Recherche en Droit, Economie, Gestion (2019–43): 1–32.
  162. ^ Dan O’Meara, Volkskapitalisme: class, capital, and beliefs within the improvement of Afrikaner nationalism, 1934–1948 (Cambridge University Press, 1983).
  163. ^ The Great Depression and the 1930S, Federal Research Division of the Library of Congress.
  164. ^ Minnaar, Anthony (1994). “Unemployment and relief measures during the Great Depression (1929–1934)”. Kleio. 26 (1): 45–85. doi:10.1080/00232084.1994.10823193.
  165. ^ Robert William Davies, Mark Harrison, and Stephen G. Wheatcroft, eds. The financial transformation of the Soviet Union, 1913–1945 (Cambridge University Press, 1994)
  166. ^ Robert Conquest, The Harvest of Sorrow: Soviet Collectivization and the Terror-Famine (1987).
  167. ^ Jennifer Burns (2009).Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right, p. 34. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-532487-0
  168. ^ “Illegal Emigration to the U.S.S.R. During the Great Depression”. www.genealogia.fi.
  169. ^ Gabriel Tortella and Jordi Palafox, “Banking and Industry in Spain 1918–1936,” Journal of European Economic History (1984), 13#2 Special Issue, pp. 81–110.
  170. ^ R.J. Harrison, Economic History of Modern Spain (1978), pp. 129–49.
  171. ^ Göran Therborn, “A Unique Chapter in the History of Democracy: The Swedish Social Democrats”, in Okay. Misgeld et al. (eds), Creating Social Democracy, University Park, Penn State University Press, 1996.
  172. ^ Charles Loch Mowat, Britain between the wars, 1918–1940 (1955) pp. 386–412.
  173. ^ Unemployment During The Great Depression Archived January 24, 2009, on the Wayback Machine, thegreatdepression.co.uk
  174. ^ Cook, Chris and Bewes, Diccon; What Happened Where: A Guide To Places And Events In Twentieth-Century History p. 115; Routledge, 1997 ISBN 1-85728-533-6
  175. ^ “Work camps that tackled Depression”, BBC News.
  176. ^ Constantine, Stephen (1983), Social Conditions in Britain 1918–1939, ISBN 0-416-36010-6
  177. ^ a b Peter Clemens, Prosperity, Depression and the New Deal: The USA 1890–1954, Hodder Education, 4. Auflage, 2008, ISBN 978-0-340-96588-7, p. 114.
  178. ^ Charles R. Morris, A Rabble of Dead Money: The Great Crash and the Global Depression: 1929–1939 (PublicAffairs, 2017), 389 pp. on-line evaluation
  179. ^ “Smoot-Hawley Tariff” Archived March 12, 2009, on the Wayback Machine, U.S. Department of State.
  180. ^ “Reconstruction Finance Corporation”. EH.internet Encyclopedia. Archived from the unique on October 29, 2013.
  181. ^ Clemens, Prosperity, Depression and the New Deal, 2008, p. 113.
  182. ^ The Great Depression (1929–1939), The Eleanor Roosevelt Papers. Archived December 23, 2008, on the Wayback Machine
  183. ^ Swanson, Joseph; Williamson, Samuel (1972). “Estimates of national product and income for the United States economy, 1919–1941”. Explorations in Economic History. 10: 53–73. doi:10.1016/0014-4983(72)90003-4.
  184. ^ “Great Depression in the United States”, Microsoft Encarta. Archived October 31, 2009. Archived March 1, 2009, on the Wayback Machine
  185. ^ Joyce Bryant, “The Great Depression and New Deal”, Yale-New Haven Teachers Institute.
  186. ^ The Dust Bowl, Geoff Cunfer, Southwest Minnesota State University. Archived December 28, 2008, on the Wayback Machine
  187. ^ “National Park History: “The Spirit of the Civilian Conservation Corps“. Nationalparkstraveler.com. Archived from the unique on September 5, 2010. Retrieved September 4, 2010.
  188. ^ Robert Goldston, The Great Depression, Fawcett Publications, 1968, p. 228.
  189. ^ Economic Fluctuations, Maurice W. Lee, Chairman of Economics Dept., Washington State College, revealed by R.D. Irwin Inc, Homewood, Illinois, 1955, p. 236.
  190. ^ Business Cycles, James Arthur Estey, Purdue University, Prentice-Hall, 1950, pp. 22–23 chart.
  191. ^ Maurice W. Lee, 1955.
  192. ^ Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. The Coming of the New Deal: 1933–1935. Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003 [1958]. ISBN 0-618-34086-6; Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. The Politics of Upheaval: 1935–1936. Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003 [1960]. ISBN 0-618-34087-4
  193. ^ Lanny Ebenstein, Milton Friedman: A Biography (2007).
  194. ^ The Grapes of Wrath, by John Steinbeck, Penguin, 2006, 0143039431, p. 238
  195. ^ David Taylor, Soul of a People: The WPA Writers’ Project Uncovers Depression America (2009).
  196. ^ Jerre Mangione, The Dream and the Deal: The Federal Writers’ Project, 1935–1943 (1996)
  197. ^ Jerrold Hirsch, Portrait of America: A Cultural History of the Federal Writers’ Project (2006)
  198. ^ Stacy I. Morgan, Rethinking Social Realism: African American artwork and literature, 1930–1953 (2004), p. 244.
  199. ^ Harry, Lou (October 1, 2010). Cincinnati Magazine. Emmis Communications. pp. 59–63. Retrieved July 10, 2017.
  200. ^ Morency, Philip. On the Aisle, Volume 2: Film Reviews by Philip Morency. Dorrance Publishing. pp. 133–. ISBN 978-1-4349-7709-0.
  201. ^ Pimpare, Stephen (2017). Ghettos, Tramps, and Welfare Queens: Down and Out on the Silver Screen. Oxford University Press. pp. 216–. ISBN 978-0-19-066072-7. Retrieved July 10, 2017.
  202. ^ Smith, Robert W. (January 26, 2006). Spotlight on America: The Great Depression. Teacher Created Resources. ISBN 978-1-4206-3218-7. Retrieved July 10, 2017.
  203. ^ a b c “When Did the Great Depression Receive Its Name? (And Who Named It?) – History News Network”. hnn.us.
  204. ^ William Manchester, The Glory and the Dream: A Narrative History of America, 1932–1972.
  205. ^ Fletcher, T.W. (1961). “The Great Depression of English Agriculture 1873–1896”. The Economic History Review. Blackwell Publishing. 13 (3): 417–32. doi:10.2307/2599512. JSTOR 2599512.
  206. ^ “Child poverty soars in eastern Europe”, BBC News, October 11, 2000.
  207. ^ See “What Can Transition Economies Learn from the First Ten Years? A New World Bank Report,” in Transition Newsletter Worldbank.org, Okay-A.kg
  208. ^ a b Who Lost Russia?, New York Times, October 8, 2000.
  209. ^ Adam Tooze, Crashed: How iters a Decade of Financial Crises Changed the World (2018) p. 41.
  210. ^ Rampell, Catherine (March 11, 2009). “Great Recession’: A Brief Etymology”. The New York Times.
  211. ^ Gibbs, Nancy (April 15, 2009). “The Great Recession: America Becomes Thrift Nation”. Time. Archived from the unique on April 17, 2009.
  212. ^ Krugman, Paul (March 20, 2009). “The Great Recession versus the Great Depression”. The New York Times.
  213. ^ Lahart, Justin (July 28, 2009). “The Great Recession: A Downturn Sized Up”. The Wall Street Journal.
  214. ^ Rabinowitz, Marco (October 6, 2011). “The Great Depression vs. the Great Recession Archived 2011-10-17 at the Wayback Machine: A look at the value of the U.S. dollar in 1929 and 2008; what has changed and where that leaves us today”. MSN Money. Benzinga.
  215. ^ Evans-Pritchard, Ambrose (September 14, 2010). “IMF Fears ‘Social Explosion’ From World Jobs Crisis”. The Daily Telegraph (London). “America and Europe face the worst jobs crisis since the 1930s and risk ‘an explosion of social unrest’ unless they tread carefully, the International Monetary Fund has warned.”

Further studying

  • Ambrosius, G. and W. Hibbard, A Social and Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe (1989)
  • Bernanke, Ben (1995). “The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach” (PDF). Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. Blackwell Publishing. 27 (1): 1–28. doi:10.2307/2077848. JSTOR 2077848.
  • Brendon, Piers. The Dark Valley: A Panorama of the Thirties (2000) complete international financial and political historical past; 816pp excerpt
  • Brown, Ian. The Economies of Africa and Asia within the Iinter-war Depression (1989)
  • Davis, Joseph S. The World Between the Wars, 1919–39: An Economist’s View (1974)
  • Drinot, Paulo, and Alan Knight, eds. The Great Depression in Latin America (2014) excerpt
  • Eichengreen, Barry. Golden Fetters: The gold commonplace and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. 1992.
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Marc Flandreau. The Gold Standard in Theory and History (1997) on-line model
  • Feinstein. Charles H. The European Economy between the Wars (1997)
  • Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960 (1963), monetarist interpretation (closely statistical)
  • Galbraith, John Kenneth, The Great Crash, 1929 (1954), in style
  • Garraty, John A. The Great Depression: An Inquiry into the causes, course, and Consequences of the Worldwide Depression of the Nineteen-Thirties, as Seen by Contemporaries and in Light of History (1986)
  • Garraty John A. Unemployment in History (1978)
  • Garside, William R. Capitalism in Crisis: worldwide responses to the Great Depression (1993)
  • Glasner, David, ed. Business Cycles and Depressions (Routledge, 1997), 800 pp. Excerpt
  • Goldston, Robert, The Great Depression: The United States within the Thirties (1968)
  • Grinin, L., Korotayev, A. and Tausch A. (2016) Economic Cycles, Crises, and the Global Periphery. Springer International Publishing, Heidelberg, New York, Dordrecht, London, ISBN 978-3-319-17780-9;
  • Grossman, Mark. Encyclopedia of the Interwar Years: From 1919 to 1939 (2000). 400 pp. worldwide protection
  • Haberler, Gottfried. The World Economy, cash, and the good despair 1919–1939 (1976)
  • Hall Thomas E. and J. David Ferguson. The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies (1998)
  • Hodson, H.V. Slump and Recovery, 1929–37 (Oxford UP, 1938). on-line 496 pp. annual histories
  • Kaiser, David E. Economic diplomacy and the origins of the Second World War: Germany, Britain, France and Eastern Europe, 1930–1939 (1980)
  • Kehoe, Timothy J. and Edward C. Prescott, eds. Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century (2007), essays by economists on US, Britain, France, Germany, Italy and on tariffs; statistical
  • Kindleberger, Charles P. The World in Depression, 1929–1939 (third ed. 2013)
  • Konrad, Helmut and Wolfgang Maderthaner, eds. Routes Into the Abyss: Coping With Crises within the Thirties (Berghahn Books, 2013), 224 pp. Compares political crises in Germany, Italy, Austria, and Spain with these in Sweden, Japan, China, India, Turkey, Brazil, and the United States.
  • Latham, Anthony, and John Heaton, The Depression and the Developing World, 1914–1939 (1981).
  • Madsen, Jakob B. “Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression”, Southern Economic Journal, Southern Economic Journal (2001) 67#4 pp. 848–68 on-line at JSTOR.
  • Markwell, Donald. John Maynard Keynes and International Relations: Economic Paths to War and Peace, Oxford University Press (2006).
  • Mitchell, Broadus. Depression Decade: From New Era by New Deal, 1929–1941 (1947), 462 pp. thorough protection of the U.S.. economic system
  • Mundell, R.A. “A Reconsideration of the Twentieth Century”, The American Economic Review Vol. 90, No. 3 (Jun. 2000), pp. 327–40 on-line model
  • Psalidopoulos, Michael, ed. The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012). ISBN 978-960-99793-6-8. Chapters by financial historians cowl Finland, Sweden, Belgium, Austria, Italy, Greece, Turkey, Bulgaria, Yugoslavia, Romania, Spain, Portugal, and Ireland. desk of contents
  • Romer, Christina D. “The Nation in Depression,” Journal of Economic Perspectives (1993) 7#2 pp. 19–39 in JSTOR, statistical comparability of U.S. and different nations
  • Rothermund, Dietmar. The Global Impact of the Great Depression (1996) Online
  • Tipton, F. and R. Aldrich, An Economic and Social History of Europe, 1890–1939 (1987)

Contemporary

  • Keynes, John Maynard. “The World’s Economic Outlook”, Atlantic (May 1932), on-line version.
  • Schumpeter, Joseph (1930). “The Present World Depression: A Tentative Diagnosis”. Available on JSTOR.
  • League of Nations, World Economic Survey 1932–33 (1934).

External hyperlinks